"Шт Univerza v Mariboru Ekonomsko-poslovna fakulteta Letnik: Z, 1 I Številka: Q I ОП1 R, I Volume:0 I | Number: O | I 1, the forecast compared has a lower degree of accuracy than the naive one. According to all accuracy indicators, the forecasts based on VAR(2) models are more accurate than the Kalman filter predictions. The positive values for mean errors of the Kalam technique forecasts suggest the tendency to underestimate the forecasts for all these methods. In the case of VAR predictions, only the dynamic simulations generated underestimated expectations. It is interesting that a considerable improvement was obtained for the Kalman filter prediction of the first space state model by adjusting the initial data using the Hodrick-Prescott filter. The second scenario of VAR predictions (dynamic-stochastic simulations) was the best according to the MASE indicator used in making comparisons. are rather commonly used in the literature: the Kalman filter method and VAR models. These methods were used to make short-term unemployment rate forecasts for Romania for 2010-2012. According to all accuracy measures, the Kalman technique predictions were underestimated and less accurate than the different scenarios of the VAR model forecasts. It seems that the causality between the first difference data series of inflation and unemployment rate helped improve the forecasting process more. The Kalman filter predictions based only on natural unemployment and cyclical component were not strong enough to generate more accurate forecasts. The superiority of VAR models in forecasting was valid only for this particular case of the Romanian economy, where we demonstrated that inflation is a cause of the unemployment rate's evolution. Another interesting strategy this article proposed to improve Kalman filter predictions is the application of the technique on adjusted data series based on another filter: the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Applying two filters to the same data set improved the predictions' accuracy in the case of the first proposed state space model. Another important conclusion is that the classical state space model used in the literature to determine the natural unemployment rate did not provide the expected results for the Romanian economy. Therefore, other, more simplistic state space models were proposed for Romania's unemployment rate. 5 Conclusions Many quantitative methods are used to make predictions. In this study, we selected two econometric techniques that All in all, this research provides pertinent results regarding the prediction of unemployment rate in Romania, but the study could be improved by comparing other predictive quantitative techniques, like Bayesian VAR or VARMA models. References 1. Allan, G. (2013). Evaluating the usefulness of forecasts of relative growth.Sire Discussion Paper,2013-10, 1-26. 2. Barnichon, R., Nekarda, C. J., Hatzius, J., Stehn, S. J., &Petrongolo, B. (2012). The Ins and Outs of Forecasting Unemployment: Using Labor Force Flows to Forecast the Labor Market [with Comments and Discussion]. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 83-131. http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/eca.2012.0018 3. Bratu, M.(2012).The reduction of uncertainty in making decisions by evaluating the macroeconomic forecasts performance in Romania. Economic Research-Scientific Journal, 25(2), 239-262. 4. Camba-Mendez, G. (2012). Conditional forecasts on SVAR models using theKalman filter.Economics Letters, 115(3), 376-378. http:// dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2011.12.087 5. Clements, M. P., & Hendry, D. F. (2003). On the limitations of comparing mean squared forecast errors (with discussion). Journal of Forecasting, 12, 617-639. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/for.3980120802 6. Franses, P. H., McAleer, M., &Legerstee, R. (2012).Evaluating macroeconomic forecasts: a concise review of some recent develop-ments.Kier Discussion Paper Series, 821, 1-29. 7. Franses, P. H., Paap, R., &Vroomen, B. (2004).Forecasting unemployment using an autoregression with censored latent effects parameters.International Journal of Forecasting, 20(2), 255-271. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016yj.ijforecast.2003.09.004 8. Heilemann, U., &Stekler, H. O. (2013). Has The Accuracy of Macroeconomic Forecasts for Germany Improved?.German Economic Review, 14(2), 235-253. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0475.2012.00569.x 9. Hodrick, R., & Prescott, E. C. (1997). Postwar U.S. business cycles: An empirical investigation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1-16. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2953682 10. Kishor, N. K., & Koenig E. F. (2012).VAR estimation and forecasting when data are subject to revisionJournal of Business & Economic Statistics, 30(2), 181-190. 11. Koopman, S.J., Shephard, N.&Doornik, J.A. ( 1999). Statistical algorithms for models in state space using SsfPack 2.2.Econometrics Journal, 2(1), 107-160. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1368-423X.00023 12. Kurita, T. (2010).A forecasting model for Japan's unemployment rate.Eurasian Journal of Business and Economics, 5(5), 127-134. 13. Lack, C. (2006).Forecasting Swiss inflation using VAR models.Swiss National Bank Economic Studies, 2. 14. Milas, C.,&Rothman, F. (2008). Out-of-sample forecasting of unemployment rates with pooled STVECM forecasts.International Journal of Forecasting, 24(1), 101-121. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijforecast.2007.12.003 15. Proietti, T. (2003). Forecasting the US unemployment rate.Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 42(3), 451-476. http://dx.doi. org/10.1016/S0167-9473(02)00230-X 16. Razzak, W. (1997). The Hodrick-Prescott technique: A smoother versus a filter: An application to New Zealand GDP.Economics Letters, 57(2), 163-168. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1765(97)00178-X 17. Robinson, W. (1998). Forecasting inflation using VAR Analysis.Bank of Jamaica.Retrieved from http://www.boj.org.jm/uploads/pdf/ papers_pamphlets/papers_pamphlets_forecasting_inflation_using_var_analysis.pdf 18. Sermpinis, G., Stasinakis, C., &Karathanasopoulos, A. (2013).Kalmanfilter and SVR combinations in forecasting US unemployment. Artificial Intelligence Applications and InnovationsIFIPAdvances in Information and Communication Technology, 412, 506-515. 19. vanDijk, D., Teräsvirta, T., &Franses, P.H. (2000). Smooth transition autoregressive models-Asurvey of recent developments. Working Paper Series in Economics andFinance, No. 380, Stockholm School of Economics. Appendix 1 Tests for Checking the Assumptions Related to the VAR Model Lag-length criteria Lag LogL LR FPE AIC SC HQ 0 -97.51033 NA 19.63724 8.653072 8.751811 8.677905 1 -89.69603 13.59009 14.13464 8.321394 8.617609 8.395891 2 -82.84189 10.72821" 11.15128" 8.073208" 8.566901" 8.197370" Residual Portmanteau test for checking errors' autocorrelation Lags O-Stat Prob. Adj O-Stat Prob. df 1 0.175105 NA" 0.183064 NA" NA" 2 1.326585 NA" 1.444209 NA" NA" 3 2.837075 0.5855 3.181272 0.5280 4 4 3.579113 0.8930 4.079529 0.8499 8 5 5.432702 0.9419 6.448004 0.8918 12 6 8.810793 0.9210 11.01836 0.8084 16 7 9.136089 0.9813 11.48598 0.9326 20 8 11.53810 0.9846 15.16906 0.9157 24 9 16.88601 0.9508 23.95490 0.6839 28 10 18.92214 0.9675 27.55730 0.6911 32 11 19.42491 0.9890 28.52093 0.8081 36 12 21.16431 0.9937 32.15787 0.8067 40 * The test is valid only for lags larger than the VAR lag order. df is degrees of freedom for (approximate) chi-square distribution Residual LM test for checking errors' homoscedasticity VAR Residual Serial Correlation LM Tests Null Hypothesis: no serial correlation at lag order h Lags LM-Stat Prob 1 0.460020 0.9773 2 2.681114 0.6125 3 2.075462 0.7219 4 0.950521 0.9172 5 1.816200 0.7695 6 3.531397 0.4731 7 0.341387 0.9870 8 3.978712 0.4089 9 6.746046 0.1499 10 2.243840 0.6910 11 0.547576 0.9687 12 3.694621 0.4489 Probs from chi-square with 4 df. VAR Residual Heteroskedasticity Tests VAR Residual Heteroskedasticity Tests: No cross-terms (only levels and squares) Joint test: Chi-sq df Prob. 25.24139 24 0.3927 Individual components: Dependent R-squared F(8,14) Prob. Chi-sq(8) res1"res1 0.322277 0.832175 0.5894 7.412368 res2"res2 0.233480 0.533044 0.8131 5.370029 res2"res1 0.625253 2.919816 0.0383 14.38082 VAR Residual Heteroskedasticity Tests: Includes cross-terms Joint test: Chi-sq df Prob. 52.21834 42 0.1342 Individual components: Dependent R-squared F(14,8) Prob. Chi-sq(14) Prob. res1*res1 0.916236 6.250420 0.0068 21.07342 0.0998 res2*res2 0.523429 0.627613 0.7870 12.03886 0.6032 res2*res1 0.929029 7.480110 0.0038 21.36766 0.0926 Jarque-Bera Test for Checking Normal Distribution Component Skewness Chi-sq df Prob. 1 0.400022 0.613399 1 0.4335 2 0.184908 0.131066 1 0.7173 Joint 0.744465 2 0.6892 Component Kurtosis Chi-sq df Prob. 1 3.034727 0.001156 1 0.9729 2 3.009473 8.60E-05 1 0.9926 Joint 0.001242 2 0.9994 Component Jarque-Bera df Prob. 1 0.614555 2 0.7354 2 0.131152 2 0.9365 Joint 0.745707 4 0.9456 Impulse-Response Analysis Response of DI: Response of DU: Period DI DU Period DI DU 1 2.685611 0.000000 1 0.217511 1.021384 2 -0.601577 -0.907380 2 0.534967 0.416467 3 -0.239417 -0.276710 3 0.837354 -0.167574 4 -0.765368 0.120726 4 0.033907 -0.446814 5 0.035891 0.370063 5 -0.333998 -0.209706 6 0.245921 0.156501 6 -0.352703 0.091735 7 0.292615 -0.074911 7 -0.031785 0.206300 8 0.013271 -0.166930 8 0.169597 0.099136 9 -0.134527 -0.076009 9 0.159855 -0.046176 10 -0.128219 0.038676 10 0.015591 -0.096744 Variance Decomposition of DU: Period S.E. DI DU 1 1.044287 4.338332 95.66167 (8.29004) (8.29004) 2 1.245058 21.51381 78.48619 (15.6848) (15.6848) 3 1.509772 45.39161 54.60839 (17.4357) (17.4357) 4 1.574867 41.76315 58.23685 (16.8917) (16.8917) 5 1.623495 43.53115 56.46885 (17.3532) (17.3532) 6 1.663896 45.93614 54.06386 (17.3496) (17.3496) 7 1.676938 45.26035 54.73965 (17.4312) (17.4312) 8 1.688405 45.65663 54.34337 (17.6840) (17.6840) 9 1.696584 46.10526 53.89474 (17.6590) (17.6590) 10 1.699412 45.96038 54.03962 (17.7893) (17.7893) Response of DI to Cholesky One S. D. Innovations — DI DU Vol. 61 No. 3 / Junij 2015 Variance Decomposition of DI: Period S.E. DI DU 1 2.685611 100.0000 0.000000 (0.00000) (0.00000) 2 2.897885 90.19570 9.804295 (10.1231) (10.1231) 3 2.920895 89.45210 10.54790 (9.83838) (9.83838) 4 3.021919 89.98595 10.01405 (9.22464) (9.22464) 5 3.044705 88.65800 11.34200 (10.4016) (10.4016) 6 3.058626 88.49921 11.50079 (10.8627) (10.8627) 7 3.073505 88.55088 11.44912 (10.8456) (10.8456) 8 3.078063 88.29066 11.70934 (11.3968) (11.3968) 9 3.081939 88.25927 11.74073 (11.6589) (11.6589) 10 3.084847 88.26568 11.73432 (11.8730) (11.8730) Response of DU to Cholesky One S. D. Innovations — DI — DU Appendix 2 ADF Test for Inflation and Unemployment Rate Null Hypothesis: D(I) has a unit root Exogenous: Constant Lag Length: 0 (Automatic—based on SIC, maxlag=6) f-Statistic Prob.* Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -5.372594 0.0002 Test critical values: 1% level -3.711457 5% level -2.981038 10% level -2.629906 *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(I,2) Method: Least Squares Variable Coefficient Std. Error f-Statistic Prob. D(I(-1)) -1.091922 0.203239 -5.372594 0.0000 C -0.024845 0.519951 -0.047783 0.9623 R-squared 0.546011 Mean dependent var -0.003846 Adjusted R-squared 0.527095 S.D. dependent var 3.855228 S.E. of regression 2.651166 Akaike info criterion 4.861680 Sum squared resid 168.6883 Schwarz criterion 4.958456 Log likelihood -61.20183 Hannan-Ouinn criter. 4.889548 F-statistic 28.86477 Durbin-Watson stat 2.014213 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000016 Null Hypothesis: D(I) has a unit root Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Lag Length: 0 (Automatic—based on SIC, maxlag=6) f-Statistic Prob.* Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -5.346732 0.0010 Test critical values: 1% level -4.356068 5% level -3.595026 10% level -3.233456 *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(I,2) Variable Coefficient Std. Error f-Statistic Prob. D(I(-1)) -1.109342 0.207480 -5.346732 0.0000 C 0.640661 1.152837 0.555725 0.5838 @TREND(1985) -0.045920 0.070771 -0.648849 0.5229 R-squared 0.554172 Mean dependent var -0.003846 Adjusted R-squared 0.515405 S.D. dependent var 3.855228 S.E. of regression 2.683736 Akaike info criterion 4.920464 Sum squared resid 165.6561 Schwarz criterion 5.065629 Log likelihood -60.96603 Hannan-Ouinn criter. 4.962266 F-statistic 14.29471 Durbin-Watson stat 2.019481 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000092 Null Hypothesis: D(I) has a unit root Exogenous: None Lag Length: 0 (Automatic—based on SIC, maxlag=6) f-Statistic Prob.* Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -5.482909 0.0000 Test critical values: 1% level -2.656915 5% level -1.954414 10% level -1.609329 *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(I,2) Method: Least Squares Variable Coefficient Std. Error f-Statistic Prob. D(I(-1)) -1.091849 0.199137 -5.482909 0.0000 R-squared 0.545968 Mean dependent var -0.003846 Adjusted R-squared 0.545968 S.D. dependent var 3.855228 S.E. of regression 2.597725 Akaike info criterion 4.784852 Sum squared resid 168.7044 Schwarz criterion 4.833240 Log likelihood -61.20307 Hannan-Quinn criter. 4.798786 Durbin-Watson stat 2.014156 Null Hypothesis: D(U) has a unit root Exogenous: Constant Lag Length: 1 (Automatic—based on SIC, maxlag=6) f-Statistic Prob.* Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -4.350208 0.0023 Test critical values: 1% level -3.724070 5% level -2.986225 10% level -2.632604 *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(U,2) Method: Least Squares Variable Coefficient Std. Error f-Statistic Prob. D(U(-1)) -0.853569 0.196213 -4.350208 0.0003 D(U(-1),2) 0.506854 0.184224 2.751288 0.0117 C 0.114034 0.241543 0.472105 0.6415 R-squared 0.465821 Mean dependent var -0.008000 Adjusted R-squared 0.417259 S.D. dependent var 1.571431 S.E. of regression 1.199591 Akaike info criterion 3.314005 Sum squared resid 31.65840 Schwarz criterion 3.460270 Log likelihood -38.42506 Hannan-Quinn criter. 3.354573 F-statistic 9.592329 Durbin-Watson stat 2.031800 Prob(F-statistic) 0.001011 Null Hypothesis: D(U) has a unit root Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Lag Length: 1 (Automatic—based on SIC, maxlag=6) f-Statistic Prob.* Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -4.375020 0.0100 Test critical values: 1% level -4.374307 5% level -3.603202 10% level -3.238054 *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(U,2) Method: Least Squares Variable Coefficient Std. Error f-Statistic Prob. D(U(-1)) -0.873002 0.199542 -4.375020 0.0003 D(U(-1),2) 0.513185 0.186062 2.758141 0.0118 C 0.512914 0.566368 0.905621 0.3754 @TREND(1985) -0.026409 0.033848 -0.780212 0.4440 R-squared 0.480869 Mean dependent var -0.008000 Null Hypothesis: D(U) has a unit root Exogenous: None Lag Length: 1 (Automatic—based on SIC, maxlag=6) f-Statistic Prob." Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -4.399596 0.0001 Test critical values: 1% level -2.660720 5% level -1.955020 10% level -1.609070 *MacKinnon (1996) one i-sided p-values. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(U,2) Method: Least Squares Variable Coefficient Std. Error f-Statistic Prob. D(U(-1)) -0.842845 0.191573 -4.399596 0.0002 D(U(-1),2) 0.501249 0.180709 2.773790 0.0108 R-squared 0.460409 Mean dependent var -0.008000 Adjusted R-squared 0.436948 S.D. dependent var 1.571431 S.E. of regression 1.179151 Akaike info criterion 3.244085 Sum squared resid 31.97914 Schwarz criterion 3.341595 Log likelihood -38.55106 Hannan-Ouinn criter. 3.271130 Durbin-Watson stat 2.021484 Appendix 3 Estimation of State Space Models Sspace: SS01 Method: Maximum likelihood (Marquardt) Coefficient Std. Error z-Statistic Prob. C(1) -0.000273 3.200618 -8.52E-05 0.9999 C(2) -0.056874 3.425824 -0.016602 0.9868 Final State Root MSE z-Statistic Prob. SV1 3.457560 707.1167 0.004890 0.9961 SV2 3.542440 707.1168 0.005010 0.9960 Log likelihood -55.56132 Akaike info criterion 4.111523 Parameters 2 Schwarz criterion 4.206680 Diffuse priors 2 Hannan-Quinn criter. 4.140614 Sspace: SS01 Method: Maximum likelihood (Marquardt) Sample: 1985-2012 Included observations: 28 Convergence achieved after 25 iterations Coefficient Std. Error z-Statistic Prob. C(1) 0.656488 0.259550 2.529331 0.0114 C(2) 0.975983 0.036640 26.63683 0.0000 Final State Root MSE z-Statistic Prob. SV1 6.831881 1.388528 4.920234 0.0000 Log likelihood -50.44527 Akaike info criterion 3.746090 Parameters 2 Schwarz criterion 3.841248 Diffuse priors 0 Hannan-Quinn criter. 3.775181 Sspace: SS01 Method: Maximum likelihood (Marquardt) Coefficient Std. Error z-Statistic Prob. C(1) 0.634768 0.241763 2.625574 0.0087 Final State Root MSE z-Statistic Prob. SV1 7.000000 1.373530 5.096359 0.0000 Log likelihood -55.54141 Akaike info criterion 4.038672 Parameters 1 Schwarz criterion 4.086251 Diffuse priors 1 Hannan-Quinn criter. 4.053217 @signal u1 = sv1 @state sv1 = c(1)*sv1(-1) + [var = exp(c(2))] Sspace: SS02 Method: Maximum likelihood (Marquardt) Sample: 1985-2012 Included observations: 28 Convergence achieved after 13 iterations Coefficient Std. Error z-Statistic Prob. C(1) 1.010108 0.011748 85.97780 0.0000 C(2) -1.869310 0.521787 -3.582511 0.0003 Final State Root MSE z-Statistic Prob. SV1 6.335985 0.392721 16.13354 0.0000 Log likelihood -20.90208 Akaike info criterion 1.635863 Parameters 2 Schwarz criterion 1.731020 Diffuse priors 1 Hannan-Ouinn criter. 1.664953 @signal u1 = svi @state svi = svi(-l) + [var = exp(c(2))] Sspace: SS02 Method: Maximum likelihood (Marquardt) Sample: 1985-2012 Included observations: 28 Convergence achieved after 9 iterations Coefficient Std. Error z-Statistic Prob. C(2) -1.837286 0.441786 -4.158767 0.0000 Final State Root MSE z-Statistic Prob. SV1 6.272583 0.399060 15.71839 0.0000 Log likelihood -21.33485 Akaike info criterion 1.595346 Parameters 1 Schwarz criterion 1.642925 Diffuse priors 1 Hannan-Ouinn criter. 1.609892 Author Mihaela Simionescu (Bratu) earned a PhD in economic cybernetics and statistics and is a senior researcher at the Institute for Economic Forecasting of the Romanian Academy and post-doctoral researcher in economics at the Romanian Academy. She is a member of the following professional associations: Romanian Regional Science Association, International Regional Science Association, Romanian Society of Econometrics, International Association of Scientific Innovation and Research, and General Association of Economists from Romania International Society of Bayesian Analysis. Kalmanov filter ali VAR-modeli za napovedovanje stopnje brezposelnosti v Romuniji? Izvleček V prispevku predstavljamo v praksi pogost ekonomski problem. Ko imamo za isto spremenljivko več napovedi, pri odločanju pa potrebujemo samo eno, je za izbiro najboljše treba te napovedi oceniti. Namen prispevka je predlagati nekaj strategij za izboljšanje napovedi stopnje brezposelnosti v Romuniji s primerjalno analizo točnosti na podlagi dveh kvantitativnih metod, Kalmanovega filtra in vektorskih avtoregresijskih modelov (VAR-modelov). Pri prvi metodi je upoštevan razvoj komponent brezposelnosti, pri VAR-modelih pa medsebojne odvisnosti med stopnjo brezposelnosti in inflacijsko stopnjo. Po Grangerjevem testu vzročnosti je inflacijska stopnja v prvi diferenci vzrok za stopnjo brezposelnosti v prvi diferenci pri stacionarnih podatkih. Za napovedi stopnje brezposelnosti v obdobju 2010-2012 v Romuniji dobimo z VAR-modeli (v vseh različicah VAR-simulacij) bolj točne napovedi kot s Kalmanovim filtrom na osnovi dveh modelov prostora stanj za vse mere točnosti. Upoštevajoč povprečno absolutno tehtano napako, so dinamične stohastične simulacije, uporabljene za napovedovanje brezposelnosti, ki temeljijo na VAR-modelu, najbolj točne. Pri drugi strategiji za izboljšanje začetnih napovedi, ki temelji na Kalmanovem filtru, so uporabljeni popravljeni podatki o brezposelnosti, transformirani s Hodrick-Prescottovim filtrom. Uporaba VAR modelov namesto različic Kalmanovega filtra je najboljša strategija za izboljšanje kakovosti napovedi stopnje brezposelnosti v Romuniji. Medsebojna povezanost med brezposelnostjo in inflacijo namreč ponuja uporabne informacije za napovedi, ki so zanesljivejše kot napovedi na osnovi razvoj brezposelnosti glede na gibanje njenih komponente (naravna brezposelnost in ciklična komponenta). Ključne besede: napovedi, točnost, Kalmanov filter, Hodrick-Prescottov filter, VAR-modeli, stopnja brezposelnosti ORIGINAL SCIENTIFIC PAPER RECEIVED: JANUARY 2015 REVISED: MAY 2015 ACCEPTED: MAY 2015 DOI: 10.1515/ngoe-2015-0010 UDK: 330.55:339.564(497.5) JEL: F1, F4, C50 Examining the Export-led Growth Hypothesis: The case of Croatia Vlatka Bilas University of Zagreb, Faculty of Economics and Business, Croatia vbiLas@efzg.hr Mile Bošnjak SKDD - CCP Smart Clear Ltd Zagreb, Croatia miLe.bosnjak@inet.hr Sanja Franc University of Zagreb, Faculty of Economics and Business, Croatia sfranc@efzg.hr Abstract This paper examines the relationship between gross domestic product and exports of goods and services in Croatia between 1996 and 2012. The research results confirmed unidirectional Granger causality from the exports of goods and services to gross domestic product. Following the EngLe-Granger approach to cointegration, long-term equilibrium as well as short-term correlation between the observed variables was identified. Exports of goods and services and gross domestic product (GDP) in Croatia move together. If the two observed variables move away from equilibrium, they will return to their long-term equilibrium state at a velocity of 24.46% in the subsequent period. In accordance with the results, we found evidence supporting the export-led growth hypothesis in Croatia. As the outcomes indicated, to recover the economy, Croatia should put more emphasis on the development of exporting sectors. Keywords: gross domestic product, export, Croatia, Granger causality NG NASE GOSPODARSTVO OUR ECONOMY Vol. . 61 No. 3 2015 pp . 22-31 1 Introduction There are extensive discussions regarding relationships between exports and economic growth (Giles & Williams, 2000), and there are four possible outcomes of investigating that relationship (Chen, 2007). First is the export-led growth hypothesis, which means that export growth causes economic growth. Export growth is typically considered one of the main determinants of an economy's growth in production and employment. Empirically, it refers to unidirectional causality from exports to gross domestic product (GDP). The second possible outcome could refer to the growth-driven export hypothesis, which postulates that a rise in GDP generally leads to a corresponding increase in exports, thereby empirically indicating unidirectional causality from GDP to exports. The third possible outcome is a bidirectional relationship between exports and economic growth. Finally, the fourth possible outcome is a neutral relationship between exports and economic growth. Most arguments in favor of an outward-oriented strategy emphasize trade openness by claiming that countries that increase their participation in international trade achieve long-term economic growth faster than countries that are less open to global trade (see, for example, World Bank, 1993). These arguments are often supported by the East Asian miracle, where the nexus between export and economic growth was evidenced during the last few decades of the 20th century. A growing development gap can be identified between countries following the export-oriented path and those based on domestic market orientation, economic protectionism, and import-led (but sooner or later unsustainable) growth. However, for countries that would like to join the group of successful exporters with a certain time lag, the change from domestic demand-generated growth to export-oriented growth is by far not easy and even less self-evident (Inotai, 2013). Croatia belongs to the latter group of countries and relies on exports as one of its development pillars. Therefore, the main goal of this paper is to test the export-led growth hypothesis in Croatia by establishing the relationship between the exports of goods and services and GDP. The paper consists of five parts. After the introductory part, the second part reviews the literature. The third part explains the methodology and data, and the fourth part provides the empirical analysis. The discussion and conclusion are included in the final part of the paper. 2 Literature Review Many studies have tried to establish the causal link between export expansion and economic growth (Khalafalla & Webb, 2001). However, empirical research on the causality issue between export and economic growth has yielded contradictory results. Contradictions like these might be partly due to the different methods, variable selections, time frames, and frequencies (Kónya, 2006). The causal link between export promotion and economic development is neither straightforward nor universal (Sung-Shen, Biswas, & Tribedy, 1990). Results of the study conducted by Doyle (1998) on the example of Ireland from 1963 to 1993 suggest that exports and GDP are cointegrated. She found evidence of short-run and long-run causality from exports to output. Meanwhile, Chen (2007) assessed the validity of the export-led growth and growth-driven export hypotheses in Taiwan by testing Granger causality using the vector error correction model and the bounds testing methodology. The results indicated that a long-run level equilibrium relationship exists among exports, output, terms of trade, and labor productivity of the model. In addition, a bidirectional causal relationship exists between exports and output in Taiwan. These results attest to the advantage of the export-led growth strategy for further growth in Taiwan (Chen, 2007). Greenway, Morgan, and Wright (1999) showed that a strong positive relationship exists between real export growth and real output growth on a sample of 69 countries for the 19751993 period. They also showed that the composition of those exports is important in determining the strength of growth. Paul and Chowdhury (1995) found evidence of Granger causality running from exports to GDP growth in Australia for the 1949-1991 period, implying that the expansion of exports promotes economic growth in Australia. McCarville and Nnadozie (1995) concluded that the Granger causality test confirmed the relationship between export growth and GDP growth in the Mexican case, as stated by development theory. In addition, Liu, Burridge, and Sinclair (2002) found bidirectional causality among economic growth, foreign direct investment (FDI), and exports in China based on monthly data between 1981 and 1997. According to the authors, these three variables appeared to be mutually reinforcing under the open-door policy. Narayan, Narayan, Prasad, and Prasad (2007) examined the export-led growth hypothesis on a sample from Fiji (19602001) and Papua New Guinea (1961-1999). Their findings suggested that, for Fiji, there is evidence of export-led growth in the long run and, for Papua New Guinea, there is evidence of export-led growth in the short run. Ekanayake (1999) used cointegration and error-correction models to analyze the causal relationship between export growth and economic growth in eight Asian developing countries for the 1960-1997 period. The results showed bidirectional causality between export growth and economic growth in seven of the eight countries in the sample. Eka-nayake's (1999) evidence showed short-run Granger causality running from economic growth to export growth in all observed cases except one (i.e., Sri Lanka). In addition, despite the strong evidence for long-run Granger causality running from export growth to economic growth in all cases, evidence of short-run causality running from export growth to economic growth occurred in only two cases: Indonesia and Sri Lanka. Biswal and Dhawan (1998) found that, in Taiwan between 1960 and 1990, the evidence indicates bidirectional causality, meaning exports and growth mutually reinforce each other. Their research further demonstrated that the causality testing results are very sensitive to model selection and to omitting variables. However, tests conducted by Afxentiou and Serletis (2000) on a sample covering 50 developing countries between 1970 and 1993 showed that export growth was not an engine of growth, not even in the cases of the Asian tigers. Their research did not support the hypothesis that export growth led to gross national product (GNP) growth in a Granger sense. Within the entire sample, only Indonesia and Oman appeared to exhibit reliable causality from export growth to GNP growth, and it is likely that their dependence on oil exports produced the obtained outcome. Causality tests from import growth to GNP growth also found that only Pakistan exhibited causality from import growth to GNP growth (Afxentiou & Serletis, 2000). Asafu-Adjaye and Chakraborty's (1999) research on the sample of four less developed countries (i.e., India, Nigeria, Fiji, and Papua New Guinea) raised doubts about policy recommendations for the less developed countries based on the export-led growth hypothesis. Furthermore, Sharma and Dhakal (1994) investigated the prima facie causal relationship between the exports and output growth in 30 developing countries between 1960 and 1988. Of the 30 countries, a feedback prima facie causal relationship between export growth and output growth was found in only five countries, whereas export growth prima facie caused output growth in six other countries. Output growth prima facie caused export growth in another eight countries, and no causal relationship was observed between output growth and export growth in the remaining 11 countries. The authors also did not find any systematic pattern in the results of low-income, middle-income, and upper middle-income countries. Kónya (2004a, 2004b) investigated the possibility of export-led growth and growth-driven export by testing Granger causality in 25 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries between 1960 and 1997. His results indicated that no causality exists between exports and growth in Luxembourg or the Netherlands; exports cause growth in Iceland; growth causes exports in Canada, Japan, and Korea; and bidirectional causality exists between exports and growth in Sweden and the United Kingdom. With less certainty, the results indicated that no causality exists between exports and growth in Denmark, France, Greece, Hungary, and Norway; exports cause growth in Australia, Austria, and Ireland; and growth causes exports in Finland, Portugal, and the United States. In Belgium, Italy, Mexico, New Zealand, Spain, and Switzerland, the results were too controversial to make a simple choice. Furthermore, some of the revealed causal relationships implied a negative delayed impact from exports to growth or vice versa. Afxentiou and Serletis (1991) further found that no systematic relationship exists between exports and GNP in industrial countries for the 1950-1985 period. According to their research results, export growth is not the magic key to GNP growth, and many of the secrets continue to be hidden, refusing to reveal themselves in a straightforward quantifiable manner. Ramos (2001) investigated the Granger causality among exports, imports, and economic growth in Portugal from 1865 to 1998. The empirical results did not confirm a unidirectional causality among the variables considered. In addition, Awokuse (2007) examined the impact of export and import expansion on growth in Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, and Poland. In the case of Bulgaria, the export-led growth hypothesis and growth-led exports hypothesis were confirmed. Empirical support existed for both the export-led growth hypothesis and import-led growth hypothesis in the Czech Republic. In Poland, only the import-led growth hypothesis was supported. These results indicate that simply focusing on the role of exports as the engine of growth might be misleading. Tang (2006) found no long- or short-run causality between export expansion and economic growth in China between 1970 and 2001 in Granger's sense. However, he found that economic growth causes import expansion in the short run. Shan and Tian (1998) also tested the export-led growth hypothesis for Shanghai, using monthly time series data from 1990 to 1996. The research found unidirectional Granger causality running from GDP to exports, implying that exceptional economic performance in Shanghai during the 1990s was not propelled by export expansion, but by a set of domestic factors and foreign investment. Hsiao (1987) investigated the existence and directions of causality between exports and GDP for Hong Kong, Taiwan, South Korea, and Singapore using Sims' unidirectional ex-ogeneity test and Granger's causality test. Using the same set of data, applied tests were shown to have different causal implications, but the one common finding from the two tests was a lack of support for the hypothesis of unidirectional causality from exports to GDP. These results imply that the rapid economic growth of countries in the sample was not only achieved with the export promotion policy, but also derived from the domestic growth of industries and import substitution. The export-led growth hypothesis was rejected in the case of Australia as well (Shan & Sun, 1998). Ahmad and Kwan (1991) found no causal link from exports to economic growth, or vice versa, on a sample of 47 African countries. Some subsets of countries provided weak support for causation running from economic growth to exports. The authors suggested the possibility of another independent factor that jointly influences both the growth of income and exports. However, the inclusion of omitted variables in the estimation of exports-income causality must remain arbitrary until a fully structural model that specifies the channels by which exports affect income and vice versa is developed (Ahmad & Kwan, 1991). As for Croatia, empirical research regarding the relationship between exports and economic growth is very scarce. Dritsaki and Stiakakis (2014) studied the relationship among FDI, exports, and economic growth in Croatia using annual time series data for 1994 to 2012. Several econometric models were applied, including the bounds testing (ARDL) approach and the ECM-ARDL model. The results confirmed a bidirectional long-run and short-run causal relationship between exports and growth. Živković, Živković, and Grdinić (2014) analyzed the relationship among GDP, the imports-coverage ratio, FDI, and gross fixed capital formation in selected Central Eastern European countries using an error-correction model. The empirical results confirmed a positive long-run influence of the imports-coverage ratio, FDI, and gross fixed capital formation on GDP growth for all of the countries except Croatia. In the case of Croatia, significant negative feedback occurred between FDI and GDP growth in the long run, but positive feedback occurred in the short run. At the micro level, Valdec and Zrnc (2014) used propensity score matching to test for causal effects of starting to export on firm performance in Croatian manufacturing firm-level data. The results confirmed that exporters have characteristics superior to those of non-exporters. In the main sample specification, pervasive evidence existed of self-selection into export markets, meaning that firms were successful years before they became exporters. 3 Methodology, Data, and Hypothesis Economic time series are often non-stationary time series. At the same time, one of the assumptions for regression model estimation is time series stationarity. For that reason, we employed the Phillips-Perron Unit Root Test to check the stationarity characteristics of the observed time series. If the variables are of the same order of integration, as is the case here, it can be assumed that they are cointegrated. For Table 1 Variable Description and Data Sources from 1996 to 2012 the purpose of testing the relationship among the variables, the error correction model or the Engle-Granger approach to cointegration (Engle & Granger, 1987) was assumed. According to this approach, a linear regression model was defined on a non-stationary time series, and then the stationarity of residuals of the defined regression model was tested. If two time series were cointegrated, then there must be Granger-causality in at least one direction. In order to empirically check causality between exports and GDP in Croatia, the Granger causality test must be applied. In this case, the test usage was a consequence of data properties, as is discussed later in the text. We found our variables of interest integrated of the same order and decided to model a non-stationary time series. Considering the research objective and available data span, we found these methods to be the most appropriate. The Granger (1969) causality test is one of the earliest and most frequently used methods developed to quantify causal effects in a time series. It is based on a generally acknowledged fact that the cause precedes the effect, which it consequently creates. It can be said that X Granger-causes Y if the past values of X can contribute to anticipating the future values of Y, which is better than using the past values of Y alone. The Granger causality test can be carried out for stationary or cointegrated time series. The Granger causality test assumes the evaluation of the following model: i=1 м where ^ is the deterministic component and £t is white noise. The null hypothesis can be tested using an F-test. If the p-value is lower than the defined level of significance, the null hypothesis is not accepted and the conclusion is that the first observed time series Granger-causes the second time series. In order to explore Granger-causality, two variables were observed: GDP level in Croatia from 1996 to 2012 at constant prices and exports of goods and services for the same period at constant prices as well. Furthermore, we tested the relationship among other GDP components for the same time period. The variable description and data sources are provided in Table 1. Variable Description Unit Source GDP GDP in Croatia 000 HRK Croatian Bureau of Statistics EGS Croatia's exports of goods and services 000 HRK Croatian Bureau of Statistics C Personal consumption in Croatia 000 HRK Croatian Bureau of Statistics G Government consumption in Croatia 000 HRK Croatian Bureau of Statistics I Investment in Croatia 000 HRK Croatian Bureau of Statistics 4 Empirical Analysis Figure 1 shows the movement of GDP, exports of goods, exports of services, and exports of both goods and services for 1996 to 2012 in Croatia. As shown in Table 2, we found GDP to be integrated at an order of two, while the exports of goods and services was integrated at the 1% empirical level of significance; thus, we assumed a long-term relationship between the observed variables. Table 2 Phillips-Perron Unit Root Test Variable p-value in levels around zero 0.99 in levels around constant 0.61 in levels with trend around constant 0.96 GDP first difference around zero 0.25 first difference around constant 0.61 first difference with trend around constant 0.80 second difference around zero 0.00 in levels around zero 0.99 in levels around constant 0.70 in levels with trend around constant 0.84 EGS first difference around zero 0.03 first difference around constant 0.02 first difference with trend around constant 0.05 second difference around zero 0.00 in levels around zero 0.99 in levels around constant 0.46 in levels with trend around constant 0.98 C first difference around zero 0.08 first difference around constant 0.19 first difference with trend around constant 0.39 second difference around zero 0.00 in levels around zero 0.73 in levels around constant 0.48 I in levels with trend around constant 0.96 first difference around zero 0.01 in levels around zero 0.99 in levels around constant 0.80 in levels with trend around constant 0.75 G first difference around zero 0.17 first difference around constant 0.18 first difference with trend around constant 0.45 second difference around zero 0.00 Source: Authors' calculations. Table 2 also indicates that the investment variable is integrated at an order of one and the other variables are integrated at an order of two. In order to determine causality between the variables of the same integration order, we employed Granger causality tests. The results are presented in Table 3. The results in Table 3 indicate causality from exports of goods and services to the GDP level in Croatia. Furthermore, the exports of goods and services Granger-cause Figure 1. GDP level, exports of goods, exports of services, and exports of goods and services in Croatia, 1996-2012 (millions of HRK) — GDP — Exports in goods — Exports in services — Exports in goods and services Source: Croatian Bureau of Statistics. Retrieved from www.dzs.hr (August, 30, 2014). Table 3 Pairwise Granger Causality Tests Pairwise Granger Causality Tests Sample: 1996 - 2012 Lags: 1 Null Hypothesis: Obs F-Statistic Prob. G does not Granger-cause C 16 1.21339 0.2906 C does not Granger-cause G 14.2909 0.0023 GDP does not Granger-cause C 16 0.00752 0.9322 C does not Granger-cause GDP 1.45383 0.2494 EGS does not Granger-cause C 16 7.16449 0.0190 C does not Granger-cause EGS 0.02769 0.8704 GDP does not Granger-cause G 16 20.6470 0.0006 G does not Granger-cause GDP 8.59429 0.0117 EGS does not Granger-cause G 16 12.4689 0.0037 G does not Granger-cause EGS 0.01042 0.9202 EGS does not Granger-cause GDP 16 10.6073 0.0062 GDP does not Granger-cause EGS 0.03242 0.8599 Source: Authors' calculations. Table 4 Long-term Relationship between GDP and Exports of Goods and Services in Croatia Dependent Variable: GDP Method: Least Squares Sample: 1996-2012 Included observations: 17 GDP = C(1) + C(2)*EGS C(1) 22449.58 9698.265 2.314804 0.0352 C(2) 2.216773 0.094976 23.34046 0.0000 R-squared 0.973204 Mean dependent var 237169.0 Adjusted R-squared 0.971417 S.D. dependent var 74876.43 S.E. of regression 12658.95 Akaike info criterion 21.84025 Sum squared resid 2.40E+09 Schwarz criterion 21.93827 Log likelihood -183.6421 Hannan-Ouinn criter. 21.84999 F-statistic 544.7770 Durbin-Watson stat 0.853790 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000 Source: Authors' calculations. Table 5 Phillips-Perron Unit Root Test of the Residuals (US) in the Long-term Equilibrium Model Null Hypothesis: US has a unit root Exogenous: None Bandwidth: 1 (Newey-West automatic) using Bartlett kernel Phillips-Perron test statistic -2.025241 0.0442 Test critical values: 1% level -2.717511 5% level -1.964418 10% level -1.605603 Source: Authors' calculations. Table 6 Short-term Relationship between GDP and Exports of Goods and Services in Croatia Dependent Variable: D2GDP Method: Least Squares Sample (adjusted): 1998-2012 Included observations: 15 after adjustments US(-1) -0.244612 0.101890 -2.400742 0.0320 R-squared 0.692751 Mean dependent var -967.4870 Adjusted R-squared 0.669116 S.D. dependent var 7273.988 S.E. of regression 4184.179 Akaike info criterion 19.63957 Sum squared resid 2.28E+08 Schwarz criterion 19.73398 Log likelihood -145.2968 Hannan-Ouinn criter. 19.63857 Durbin-Watson stat 2.157031 Source: Authors' calculations. personal consumption (C) as well as government consumption (G) while government consumption Granger-causes GDP. At the same time, GDP Granger-causes government consumption, and personal consumption Granger-causes government consumption (G). We found no cointegration between the GDP level and government expenditure level (p-value = 0.12). Therefore, we defined the GDP level as the dependent variable and exports of goods and services as the independent variable in the assumed linear regression model. The estimated results are shown in Table 4. As shown in Table 4, we found a strong relationship between GDP level and the level of exports of goods and services in Croatia. Changes in the GDP level in 97.32% of the cases move together with changes in the level of exports of goods and services in Croatia. After we estimated the long-term equilibrium between the observed variables, we tested stationarity characteristics of residuals from the estimated long-term relationship model (US). As Table 5 demonstrates, at the 5% level of significance, we found stationary residuals in the long-term equilibrium model. In order to model the short-term relationship between the observed variables, we applied a stationary time series. As variables are integrated at an order of two, we used the variables in the second difference and residuals in the long-term equilibrium model levels. The results are shown in Table 6. The estimated results in Table 6 indicate that the GDP level and exports of goods and services move together. The coefficient with the variable US(-1) is significant and in accordance with theoretical assumptions (negative). If the two observed variables move away from equilibrium, they will return to equilibrium at a velocity of 24.46%. In other words, if the two observed variables move away from the state of their long-term equilibrium over time, in the next period they will speedily return to the state of their long-term equilibrium. In addition, there is a strong relationship between GDP development and exports of goods and services in the long term. Moreover, as the Granger causality test results indicate, the influence from exports to GDP might occur through personal consumption or government consumption. In order to check the assumptions of the illustrated model, White's test for homoscedasticity of variance, the Jarque-Bera test for normality of residuals, and the test for the autocorrelation of the residuals were run (see Appendix). Following these, it was established that the assumptions of the model were met at the 95% confidence level. Coefficient Std. Error f-Statistic Prob. Adj. f-Stat Prob. Variable Coefficient Std. Error f-Statistic Prob. D2EGS 0.745318 0.136327 5.467143 0.0001 5 Discussion and Conclusion Regarding the relationship between exports and economic growth, as has been noted, some analysts believe that the causality direction is from export to economic growth, which is expressed as the export-led growth hypothesis (Balassa, 1978; Bhagwati, 1978; Edwards, 1998). In addition, various studies support growth-led export in a way that the causality direction is from economic growth to export growth. Regarding the growth-led exports hypothesis, an increase in exports is supported through the benefits of efficiency caused by the increase in the national workforce's skill levels and technology advancement (Bhagwati, 1978; Krugman, 1984). These two approaches do not overlap. Studies dealing with developed countries usually show that trade openness can have a positive impact on economic growth, especially in the long run, through the import of high-tech products, spillover effects resulting from FDI (Grossman & Helpman, 1990), and various reforms and programs that aim to create better conditions for participation in international markets (Ram, 1987). There is also the possibility that no relationship exists or just a simple contemporaneous relationship exists between these two variables. The research results presented in this paper suggest unidirectional causality from exports of goods and services to GDP level in Croatia. Furthermore, we found several influence channels from exports of goods and services to GDP. Exports of goods and services Granger-cause personal consumption (C), personal consumption (C) Granger-causes government consumption (G), and government consumption (G) Granger-causes GDP. Exports of goods and services Granger-cause government consumption (G), which Granger-causes GDP, and GDP Granger-causes government consumption (G). The empirical evaluation herein leads to the conclusion that, in Croatia, the growth of exports of goods and services Granger-causes GDP growth. Moreover, exports of goods and services and GDP in Croatia move together. If the two observed variables move away from equilibrium, they will return to equilibrium at a velocity of 24.46 % in the next period. The results of this research suggest that an export-led growth model can be acceptable for achieving economic growth and development in Croatia. In accordance with the results, we found that Croatia should put more emphasis on exports development and improvement of its trade relations. However, this research does have limitations, as reflected in its coverage and scope. It would be interesting to examine in detail which measures or policies Croatia should apply. Furthermore, a study that would establish separate relationships between exports of goods and GDP as well as between exports of services and GDP would perhaps give different results. References 1. Afxentiou, P. C., & Serletis, A. (1991). Exports and GNP Causality in the Industrial Countries: 1950-1985. Kyklos, 44(2), 167-179. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6435.1991.tb02095.x 2. Afxentiou, P. C., & Serletis, A. (2000). Output growth and variability of export and import growth: international evidence from Granger causality tests. Developing Economies, 38(2), 141-163. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1746-1049.2000.tb00874.x 3. Ahmad, J., & Kwan, A. C. C. (1991). Causality between exports and economic growth. Empirical evidence from Africa. Economics Letters, 37, 243-248. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(91)90218-A 4. Asafu-Adjaye, J., & Chakraborty, D. (1999). Export-led growth and import compression: further time series evidence from LDCs. Australian Economic Papers, June, 164-175. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1467-8454.00049 5. Awokuse, T. O. (2007). Causality between exports, imports, and economic growth: Evidence from transition economies. Economics Letters, 94, 389-395. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2006.08.025 6. Balassa, B. (1978). Exports and economic growth: Further evidence. Journal of Development Economics, 5, 181-189. http://dx.doi. org/10.1016/0304-3878(78)90006-8 7. Bhagwati, J. N. (1978). Anatomy and consequences of exchange control regimes. New York: Ballinger Publishing. 8. Biswal, B., & Dhawan, U. (1998). Export-led growth hypothesis: cointegration and causality analysis for Taiwan. Applied Economics Letters, 5, 699-701. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/135048598354159 9. Chen, S-W. (2007). Exactly what is the link between export and growth in Taiwan? New evidence from the Granger causality test. Economics Bulletin, 6(7), 1-10. 10. Croatian Bureau of Statistics. (2014). CBS Databases. Retrieved from http://www.dzs.hr/default_e.htm 11. Doyle, E. (1998). Export-output causality: The Irish case 1953-93. Atlantic Economic Journal, 26(2), 147-161. http://dx.doi. org/10.1007/BF02299357 12. Dritsaki, C., & Stiakakis, E. (2014). Foreign direct investments, exports, and economic growth in Croatia: A time series analysis. Procedia Economics and Finance, 14(14), 181-190. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(14)00701-1 13. Edwards, S. (1998). Openness, productivity and growth: What do we really know? Economic Journal, 108(447), 383-398. http://dx.doi. org/10.1111/1468-0297.00293 14. Ekanayake, E. M. (1999). Exports and economic growth in Asian developing countries: Cointegration and error-correction models. Journal of Economic Development, 24(2), 43-56. 15. Engle, R. F., & Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Co-integration and error correction: Representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica, 55(2), 251-276. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1913236 16. Giles, J. A., & Williams, C. L. (2000). Export-led growth: A survey of the empirical literature and some noncausality results part 1. Econometrics Working Paper EWP0001. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09638190050086177 17. Granger, C. W. J. (1969). Investigating causal relations by econometric models and cross-spectral methods. Econometrica, 37(3), 424-438. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1912791 18. Greenway, D., Morgan, W., & Wright, P. (1999). Exports, export composition and growth. The Journal of International Trade and Economic Development, 8(1), 41-51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09638199900000004 19. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1990). Comparative advantage and long-run growth. American Economic Review, 80, 796-815. 20. Hsiao, M. W. (1987). Tests of causality and exogeneity between exports and economic growth: The case of Asian NICs. Journal of Economic Development, 12(2), 143-159. 21. Inotai, A. (2013). Sustainable growth based on export-oriented economic strategy. Sofia: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung. 22. Khalafalla, K. Y., & Webb, A. J. (2001). Export-led growth and structural change: evidence from Malaysia. Applied Economics, 33, 1703-1715. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840010015066 23. Kónya, L. (2004a). Export-led growth, growth-driven export, both or none? Granger causality analysis on OECD countries. Applied Econometrics and International Development, 4(1), 73-94. 24. Kónya, L. (2004b). Unit-root, cointegration and Granger causality test results for export and growth in OECD countries. International Journal of Applied Econometrics and Quantitative Studies, 1(2), 67-94. 25. Kónya, L. (2006). Exports and growth: Granger causality analysis on OECD countries with a panel data approach. Economic Modelling, 23, 978-992. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2006.04.008 26. Krugman, P. R. (1984). Import protection as export promotion. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 27. Liu, X., Burridge, P., & Sinclair, P. J. N. (2002). Relationships between economic growth, foreign direct investment and trade: evidence from China. Applied Economics, 34, 1433-1440. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840110100835 28. McCarville, M., & Nnadozie, E. (2001). Causality tests of export-led growth: The case of Mexico. Atlantic Economic Journal, 23(2), 140-145. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02300439 29. Narayan, P. K., Narayan, S., Prasad, B. C., & Prasad, A. (2007). Export-led growth hypothesis: evidence from Papua New Guinea and Fiji. Journal of Economic Studies, 34(4), 341-351. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/01443580710826380 30. Paul, S., & Chowdhury, K. (1995). Export-led growth hypothesis: some empirical testing. Applied Economics Letters, 2, 177-179. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/135048595357384 31. Ram, R. (1987). Exports and economic growth in developing countries: evidence from time series and cross-section data. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 36, 51-72. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/451636 32. Ramos, F. F. R. (2001). Exports, imports, and economic growth in Portugal: evidence from causality and cointegration analysis. Economic Modelling, 8, 613-623. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0264-9993(00)00055-9 33. Shan, J., & Sun, F. (1998). Export-led growth hypothesis for Australia: an empirical re-investigation. Applied Economics Letters, 5, 423-428. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/135048598354555 34. Shan, J., & Tian, G. G. (1998). Causality between exports and economic growth: the empirical evidence from Shanghai. Australian Economic Papers, June, 195-202. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1467-8454.00015 35. Sharma, S. C., & Dhakal, D. (1994). Causal analyses between exports and economic growth in developing cou0ntries. Applied Economics, 26, 1145-1157. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036849400000112 36. Sung-Shen, N., Biswas, B., & Tribedy, G. (1990). Causality between exports and economic growth: An empirical study. Journal of Economic Development, 15(1), 47-61. 37. Tang, T. C. (2006). New evidence on export expansion, economic growth and causality in China. Applied Economic Letters, 13, 801-803. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504850500425303 38. Valdec, M., & Zrnc, J. (2014). The direction of causality between exports and firm performance: microeconomic evidence from Croatia using the matching approach. Financial Theory and Practice, 1. 39. World Bank. (1993). The East Asian miracle: Economic growth and public policy. New York: Oxford University Press. 40. Živković, S., Živković, I., & Grdinić, M. (2014). A VECM approach to detangling growth, exports, imports and FDI knot in selected CEE countries. Croatian Operational Research Review, 5, 161-175. http://dx.doi.org/10.17535/crorr.2014.0005 Appendix Table 7 White Heteroskedasticity Test F-statistic 2.873553 Prob. F(3,11) 0.0847 Obs*R-squared 6.590496 Prob. Chi-Square(3)0.0862 Scaled explained SS 3.181509 Prob. Chi-Square(3)0.3645 Source: Authors' calculations. -1090.547 -1424.374 6007.705 -7351.638 3870.735 0.209756 2.417840 0.321813 0.851372 Table 8 Correlogram Sample: 1998-2012 Included observations: 15 Autocorrelation Partial Correlation AC PAC 0-Stat Prob . "I . I . "I . I 1 -0.187 -0.187 0.6340 0.426 . ""I . I . ""I . I 2 -0.270 -0.316 2.0627 0.357 . i" . I . I . I 3 0.088 -0.043 2.2271 0.527 . i . I . "I . I 4 -0.015 -0.102 2.2323 0.693 . I" . I . I" . I 5 0.178 0.195 3.0366 0.694 . I . I . I . I 6 -0.039 0.027 3.0795 0.799 . ""I . I . "I . I 7 -0.214 -0.120 4.5350 0.717 . "I . I . ""I . I 8 -0.101 -0.250 4.9095 0.767 . I" . I . I . I 9 0.202 0.040 6.6479 0.674 . "I . I . ""I . I 10 -0.181 -0.296 8.3190 0.598 . I . I . I . I 11 -0.032 -0.046 8.3855 0.678 . I" . I 12 0.119 0.020 9.5946 0.651 Source: Authors' calculations. Figure 2. Jarque-Bera normality test 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0^-1-1- -7500 -5000 -2500 Source: Authors' calculations. 2500 5000 Series: Residual Sample 1998 20 Observations 15 Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera Probability 7500 8 0 Authors Vlatka Bilas currently works at the Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Zagreb, as an associate professor in the International Economic Department. She actively participates in preparing and conducting classes for the courses International Economics and Regional Economic Integrations at the Faculty of Economics and Business as well as Entrepreneurship and Exports in High Technologies at Faculty of Electrical Engineering and Computing, University of Zagreb. The author has participated in various professional and scientific projects, workshops, and more than 20 scientific conferences. She has published more than 70 papers. Mile Bošnjak currently works as the manager of risk control in SKDD-CCP Smart Clear Ltd. He earned his doctorate degree in international economics from the Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Zagreb. Bošnjak also works in the International Economic Department at the Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Zagreb, and at the School of Health Studies, University of Mostar, as a subcontracted teaching assistant. He has published several papers and has participated in several international conferences. Sanja Franc currently works at the Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Zagreb, as a senior assistant in the International Economic Department. She actively participates in preparing and conducting classes for the courses International Economics and Regional Economic Integrations at the Faculty of Economics and Business, University of Zagreb. The author has participated in various professional and scientific projects and workshops and has conducted lectures at more than 15 scientific conferences. She has published more than 50 scientific and professional papers. Testiranje hipoteze o izvozno podprti rasti: primer Hrvaške Izvleček V članku preverjamo povezanost bruto domačega proizvoda in izvoza blaga in storitev na Hrvaškem v obdobju med letoma 1996 in 2012. Izsledki raziskave potrjujejo enosmerno Grangerjevo vzročnost od izvoza blaga in storitev do bruto domačega proizvoda. Skladno z Engle-Grangerjevim pristopom h kointegraciji smo ugotovili dolgoročno ravnovesje in kratkoročno korelacijo med opazovanimi spremenljivkami. Izvoz blaga in storitev in bruto domači proizvod se na Hrvaškem gibljejo skupaj. Če se gibanje opazovanih spremenljivk odmakne od ravnovesja, se v naslednjem obdobju vrnejo v dolgoročno stanje ravnovesja s hitrostjo 24,46 %. Skladno z izsledki smo potrdili hipotezo o izvozno podprti rasti na Hrvaškem. Rezultati nakazujejo, da bi morala Hrvaška za okrevanje gospodarstva večji poudarek dati razvoju izvoznih sektorjev. Ključne besede: bruto domači proizvod, izvoz, Hrvaška, Grangerjeva vzročnost ORIGINAL SCIENTIFIC PAPER RECEIVED: MARCH 2015 REVISED: MAY 2015 ACCEPTED: MAY 2015 DOI: 10.1515/ngoe-2015-0011 UDK: 347.7 JEL: K22 NG NASE GOSPODARSTVO OUR ECONOMY VoL. . 61 No. 3 2015 . 32-40 Safeguarding Creditors in the Course of Simplified Reduction of Subscribed Capital Gregor Drnovšek Cankarjeva uLica 25 a, Maribor, Slovenia gregor.drnovsek1@teLemach.net Abstract The central characteristics of simplified subscribed capital reduction are its very narrow purpose, and a weakened regime of safeguarding of creditors. The main and, frankly, only purpose of the institution is recovery. It is namely most difficult to expect from a distressed company undergoing simplified subscribed capital reduction, which is first and foremost intended for recovery, to safeguard its creditors in the same extent as in the case of ordinary reduction of subscribed capital. The article provides an analysis of the intent and purpose of simplified subscribed capital reduction and the regulations governing the safeguarding of creditors. Using a descriptive method, subject matter analysis, and comparative Legal analysis of the issue, the article elaborates on why regulations governing the safeguarding of creditors are too weak with regard to the effects brought forth by this type of subscribed capitaL reduction and proposes appropriate suppLementation and amendments to appLicabLe LegisLation. Keywords: simplified subscribed capital reduction, safeguarding of creditors, capitaL inadequacy, payment ban, tied assets 1 Introduction The central characteristics of simplified subscribed capital reduction are the direct opposite of characteristics of an ordinary subscribed capital reduction: a narrow aim and purpose, and a weakened regime for safeguarding of creditors (compared to safeguards applied in ordinary subscribed capital reduction).1 The main and only purpose of this specific type of capital reduction is the recovery of a distressed company. The law breaks down the institution into three specific purposes: covering of carried-forward loss, covering of fiscal year net loss, and reallocation of assets from subscribed capital to capital reserves (first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-12). It is namely difficult to expect from a company in financial distress, which is undergoing simplified subscribed capital reduction with the sole purpose of recovery, to uphold the same creditors safeguarding regime as with ordinary subscribed capital reduction. Maintaining a broad extent of safeguards for the creditors would hinder the recovery of the company, while on the other hand—at least in most cases—resulting in a disproportionate infringement of the position of creditors, who are already at risk due to the losses realized by the company, 1 For details with regard to ordinary subscribed capital reduction, see Drnovšek (2012 and 2013). 2 Companies Act, Official Journal of the Republic of Slovenia, No. 42/2006 with subsequent amendments and revisions. not only (or, more accurately not as late as) the subscribed capital reduction. The reduction is namely executed in order to adjust the amount of subscribed capital to the (already) reduced financial position of the company, or to reallocate subscribed capital to another category of tied-up capital, and does not result in (additional) reduction of assets (on grounds of reducing the subscribed capital).3 With regard to simplified subscribed capital reduction, the recovery effect is achieved by transferring predetermined amounts from the categories of subscribed capital, capital reserves and reserves from profit into balance sheet items referred to in the first sentence of the first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1.4 As there is no fresh (external) capital injection, legal theory also refers to the institution as "book recovery".5 The simplification of the subscribed capital reduction, as opposed to the ordinary reduction, is seen from the first paragraph of Article 379, and from the reference stipulated by the third paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1. The former restricts the aim and purpose of the institution and thus takes away some of the authority of the general meeting which the latter holds in case of ordinary subscribed capital reduction. On the other hand, the released amount of the subscribed capital is easier to utilize, since it does not fall under the time-consuming regime of safeguarding of creditors, stipulated by Article 375 of ZGD-1 (the third paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1 namely fails to reference the aforementioned provision). 6 Since the safeguarding regime does not apply, as is the case with ordinary subscribed capital reduction, the execution of the measure may largely be accelerated. Weakened safeguarding of creditors does not mean that the legal regulation is disregarding the interests of creditors, since their interests are safeguarded in a different manner—a manner more suitable for the institution of simplified subscribed capital reduction. However, the safeguarding regime only goes half way, as the protection, such as currently constructed, is too weak. The forgoing thesis will be elaborated on and proven by means of descriptive method and subject matter analysis of the regulation of safeguarding of creditors in the course of simplified subscribed capital reduction. The findings will be additionally 3 Cf. Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 229, line number (hereinafter: l. no.) 1, 4); Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, Vorb. § 229, l. no. 1).. 4 Accord with reference to German law Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 229, l. no. 6). 5 Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 229, l. no. 6); Wirth (1996, p. 867). Cf. Schmidt (1982, p. 520); Kocbek in Korporacijsko pravo (Ivanjko et al., 2009, p. 729). 6 Cf. Kocbek in Korporacijsko pravo (Ivanjko et al., 2009, p. 729). In German law, cf. Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 229, l. no. 4); Wirth (1996, p. 867). fortified by means of comparative analysis of the regulation in the German legal environment. 2 Recovery and Covering Losses Pursuant to the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1, simplified subscribed capital reduction is admissible only if, after prior utilization of net profit and carried-forward profit and after the release of appropriate reserves from profit and capital reserves, the company has at its disposal statutory reserve-fund, the amount of which does not exceed the maximum amount prescribed by the law (10%, as per the third paragraph of Article 64 and first indent of the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1) or corporate charter, which is to be determined on grounds of the new (reduced) amount of subscribed capital.7 Such a threshold is stipulated also by the first point of the tenth paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1, which governs the utilization of statutory8 and capital reserves at the point of preparation and adoption of the annual report in cases when statutory reserve-fund does not exceed the threshold stipulated by the law or corporate charter. In the aforementioned instance, statutory and capital reserves may be utilized to cover the net or carried-forward loss only if the losses cannot be covered by carried-forward or net profit, or by corresponding (equal) reserve and profit categories. It is thus possible that both situations arise simultaneously, i.e. the situation referred to in the first point of the tenth paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1, and the one referred to in the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1. In such an instance, no situation has priority over the other, since the law leaves the decision whether to utilize the last available reserve (as per the first point of the tenth Paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1) or reduce the subscribed capital (as per Article 379 of ZGD-1) to the company.9 By allowing for simplified subscribed capital reduction even when the company (still) has at its disposal statutory reserve-fund, the amount of which (determined on grounds of reduced subscribed capital) does not exceed the threshold stipulated by law or corporate charter, the regulation 7 For assumptions and requirements of simplified subscribed capital reduction in continental legal systems in general, see Bratina, Jovanovič, Podgorelec, Primec (2011, p. 674). 8 Statutory reserves are the reserves referred to in the first indent of the second paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1 (Liabilities and Equity A. III. 1.). 9 By reference to the third paragraph of § 150 and § 229 of the German AktG ("Aktiengesetz"), accord Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 229, l. no. 33). Cf. Wirth (1996, p. 869 (left line)). clearly suggests that capital inadequacy10 is not a mandatory requirement for the execution of simplified subscribed capital reduction. In case the company realized a loss equal (at most) to such amount of statutory reserve-fund, and the company has no other available reserves which could be utilized to cover the loss, capital inadequacy is not given, whereas it is still admissible to reduce the subscribed capital in order to cover the loss. In all likelihood, the company will decide to cover the loss by means of simplified subscribed capital reduction (only) after capital inadequacy occurs. 2.1 Defining loss and time Article 379 of ZGD-1 uses the following terms: "car-ried-forward loss", "fiscal year net loss", "fiscal year net profit", and "carried-forward profit". The wording of the law may lead a casual reader to erroneously assume that simplified subscribed capital reduction may only be used to cover the loss of the (full) fiscal year or used only to remedy the balance disclosed in the annual balance sheet (balance sheet as at the last day of the fiscal year; cf. fourth indent of the fourth paragraph of Article 53 of ZGD-1). However, such a superficial interpretation of the law does not pass even the most basic grammatical test. The reasons why the aforementioned assumptions are false are the following: a) The awkward wording of Article 370 of ZGD-1 is nothing but a (useless) nod to the wording of the law with regard to general regulations governing balance sheet law (Part I, Chapter 8; cf. only Article 64 and Article 66 of ZGD-1), and does not denote a content-related restriction of the applicability of simplified subscribed capital reduction. The term "fiscal year net loss" should not be understood verbatim, and the term "carried-forward loss" should not be understood as only the carried-forward loss disclosed in the annual balance sheet.11 Even special provisions of ZGD-1 governing subscribed capital reduction cannot sufficiently support the assumption that simplified subscribed capital reduction can only be applied as per the annual 10 The term capital inadequacy denotes a situation when the subscribed capital had already been eaten into. We refer to capital inadequacy when the sum total of the net loss and carried-for-ward loss, reduced by potential carried-forward profit or net profit, exceeds the sum total of capital reserves and reserves from profit. As a result, the amount of own capital is below the amount of subscribed capital. Cf. Wirth (1996, p. 869 (left line)); Podgorelec (2006, p. 1673); Kobal, Prikriti prenosi premoženja in prikrita izplačila dobička (2007, p. 136). 11 Cf. Kocbek (2013, p. 359-360), who represents the opinion that simplified subscribed capital reduction, executed with the aim to cover the loss, may also be executed on grounds of an interim balance sheet which discloses the net loss as at the balance sheet cut-off date. balance sheet cut-off date, since ordinary subscribed capital reduction allows for the covering of losses and reallocation of assets to capital reserves as well. It is thus completely illogical that such a restriction is foreign to the freedom arising from the intent and purpose of ordinary subscribed capital reduction, while on the other hand limiting the very type of subscribed capital reduction, which, by definition of the law, is primarily intended for recovery, only to the balance at year-end and thus forcing the company (in need of recovery) to maintain its distressed position, deepen its loss and wait for some "magical moment". In simple terms: the aim of Article 60 of the ZGD-F amendment (enacted in 2001)12 was not to change the content-related applicability of subscribed capital reduction. The aim of the changed provision, which, unfortunately, resulted in a grand failure, was to harmonize the terminology (the omission of the wording "compensate for lower value of assets" is not relevant to this analysis).13 b) According to ZGD-1, the concentration of effects of simplified subscribed capital reduction to the last day of the past fiscal year (fiscal year which ended prior to the decision on subscribed capital reduction) is impossible. Simplified subscribed capital reduction becomes effective with the registration of the decision on reduction into the court registry (third paragraph of Article 379 in relation with Article 374 of ZGD-1), whereas the reduction cannot have retroactive effects, i.e. cannot apply to the cut-off date of the balance sheet of the past fiscal year, and thus cannot change the (possibly previously adopted) annual report.14 In other words, if the decision on executing a simplified subscribed capital reduction in order to cover the loss is not taken by the general meeting, which is to be held on the cut-off date of the annual balance sheet (see below), simplified subscribed capital reduction cannot be used to cover the fiscal year net loss, since the net loss will turn into carried-forwards loss on the very next day. 12 Act amending the Companies Act (Official Journal of RS, No. 45/2001). 13 Prior to the ZGD-F amendment, the first sentence of the first paragraph of Article 354 of ZGD-1 read: "Reduction of subscribed capital aiming to compensate for lower asset value, cover losses or reallocate assets to reserves, may be executed in a simplified manner." After the enactment of the ZGD-F amendment (Article 60), the provision read: "Reduction of subscribed capital reduction aiming to cover carried-forward loss or fiscal year net loss or reallocate assets to capital reserves may be executed in a simplified manner". Currently, the first sentence of the first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1 reads as follows (practically unchanged): "Reduction of subscribed capital aiming to cover carried-forward loss or fiscal year net loss or reallocate assets to capital reserves may be executed also in a simplified manner." 14 For retrospective effects of simplified subscribed capital reduction in German law see § 234 of the German AktG. c) A concentration of effects arising from simplified subscribed capital reduction executed on the last day of the past fiscal year may lead to the very same consequences (effects) which the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1 intends to prevent. If, during the period since the end of the past fiscal year until the decision on simplified subscribed capital reduction, the company realized profit which may be utilized to cover the loss, either partially or fully, simplified subscribed capital reduction is not permissible for that amount of the loss (perhaps even the full loss) which the company is able to cover with the realized profit.15 2.2 Determining loss and quality of loss The loss to be covered with simplified subscribed capital reduction shall exist at the time of the general meeting decision.16 The reason why the loss was realized and the amount of the loss are irrelevant,17 however, the quality of the loss needs to justify the intended permanent change of subscribed capital.18 Relevant quality of the loss is not given, if, e.g., the company discloses a loss which may be quickly remedied by future gains.19 Simplified subscribed capital reduction is thus not based solely on absolute facts, but rather, to a certain extent, also on projections of the management, which need to be drawn up with sufficient diligence.20 The loss does not need to be determined in the formal annual report, and the annual report—even a previously audited and finally adopted report—cannot serve as grounds for simplified subscribed capital reduction as long as there is a chance that the company realized profit in the meantime.21 Statutory provisions governing simplified subscribed capital reduction do not provide any instructions on 15 Cf. Kocbek (2013, p. 360-361). 16 Accord Wirth (1996, p. 868 (top right line)); Hüffer (2010, § 229, l. no. 7); Kocbek (2013, p. 360). 17 Accord Krieger in Münchener Handbuch—Aktiengesellschaft (Hoffmann-Becking et al., 2007, § 61, l. no. 6); Hüffer (2010, § 229, l. no. 7-8). 18 Krieger in Münchener Handbuch—Aktiengesellschaft (Hoffmann-Becking et al., 2007, § 61, l. no. 6); Hüffer (2010, § 229, l. no. 8), who expressly emphasizes the permanency of the loss. 19 Similar Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 229, l. no. 22); Krieger in Münchener Handbuch—Aktiengesellschaft (Hoffmann-Becking et al., 2007, § 61, l. no. 6). Cf. Wirth (1996, p. 868 (right line)). 20 This conclusion is obvious already from the wording of the law, since there is always a certain time period between the decision on capital reduction and its effect (i.e. registration in the court registry). 21 In German law cf. Wirth (1996, p.. 868 (bottom right and top right lines)); Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, § 229, l. no. 11). how to determine the loss, or instructions on the disclosure of the loss in financial statements. As a result, simplified subscribed capital reduction does not need to be based on a formal, previously drawn up balance sheet disclosing the loss which needs to be covered.22 A diligent assessment and projection of the management are fully sufficient.23 In practice, the management would still draw up an interim balance sheet in order to quantify the loss and determine the categories stipulated by the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1. However, the balance sheet does not need to be audited (despite the company potentially being obligated to audit its annual report), or adopted in any formal manner24 (e.g., by the supervisory board). The obligation to draw up an interim balance sheet, which would need to be presented to the general meeting when deciding on simplified subscribed capital reduction, is not prescribed even by Article 19 of the Decree on the registration of companies and other legal entities in the register of companies.25 The management may draw up the balance sheet referred to in the second point of Article 19 of the Decision even after the general meeting decision (and will be obligated to do so, since the management will need to present relevant items as at the date of decision of the general meeting). 3 Aim and Purpose of Reduction of Subscribed Capital If the position of creditors is endangered (already) by a negative development of the company's financial position, (subsequent) recovery is only to their benefit. The peremptory nature of the aim of simplified subscribed capital reduction and its strict limitation to recovery purposes is thus instituted with the main objective of safeguarding the creditors. Instead of directly safeguarding the claims of creditors of the company (as is the case with ordinary subscribed capital reduction pursuant to Article 375 of ZGD-1), the institution of simplified subscribed capital reduction is aimed (solely) at the improvement of the financial position of the debtor (company).26 The very concept of simplified subscribed capital reduction is thus based on the irrefutable assumption that the measure is beneficial, 22 Accord Krieger in Münchener Handbuch—Aktiengesellschaft (Hoffmann-Becking et al., 2007, § 61, l. no. 6). Cf. Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, § 229, l. no. 11 (end)). 23 Cf. Krieger in Münchener Handbuch—Aktiengesellschaft (Hoffmann-Becking et al., 2007, § 61, l. no. 6); Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, § 229, l. no. 13). 24 Similarly, Krieger in Münchener Handbuch—Aktiengesellschaft (Hoffmann-Becking et al., 2007, § 61, l. no. 7). 25 Decree on the registration of companies and other legal entities in the register of companies (Official Journal of RS, No. 43/2007 with subsequent amendments and revisions). 26 Cf. Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 229, l. no. 14). or at least, neutral, to creditors.27 Assets released by the reduction shall therefore be utilized only for recovery purposes (cf. first and second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1), whereas no payments to shareholders are permitted. Even dividend payments from future profits (and other disposal of distributable profit) are restricted (Article 380 of ZGD-1). 4 Payment Ban, Fulfilment of Intent, and Tied Assets With regard to simplified subscribed capital reduction, the main replacement for Article 375 of ZGD-1 is provided by the ban on utilization of released assets for payments to shareholders (released assets shall not be used for payments to shareholders or used as a waiver of the shareholders' obligation to pay contributions).28 Released assets (first and second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1) shall be utilized only for the fulfilment of the primary intent and purpose of simplified subscribed capital reduction (first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1). However, the law fails to provide any specific provisions on the latter (as, e.g., § 230 of the German AktG) in the part referring to the simplified reduction of subscribed capital (Articles 379 and 380 of ZGD-1). The aforementioned rule is the result of a very narrow and restrictive intent and purpose of simplified subscribed capital reduction (first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1), and (general) rules on preservation of capital (first paragraph of Article 227 and eighth paragraph of Article 230 of ZGD-1) which still apply to simplified subscribed capital reduction. In other words, while in case of ordinary subscribed capital reduction the repayment of contributions is admissible and even common practice, payments in case of simplified subscribed capital reduction are never admissible. The amount of tied-up capital is not changed due to simplified subscribed capital reduction.29 With regard to released assets and safeguarding of creditors, it is therefore sufficient to denote that the assets concerned shall only be utilized to fulfil a narrow and restrictive (admissible) intent and purpose. Moreover, the law, at least partially, remedies the disadvantages for creditors which arise from the abrogation of contingent subscribed capital (Article 380 of ZGD-1).30 As a means of remedying the haircuts to the basic guaranteed asset base, the regulation calls for the accelerated channeling of profit to tied-up reserves. By allowing the utilization of released assets only for the fulfilment of intents and purposes stipulated by the first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1, the law prevents the general meeting from releasing an excessive amount of subscribed capital in order to create available assets for payments to shareholders.31 4.1 Force and extent of tying nature of assets The narrow purpose and the ban on channeling assets to shareholders applies to all released assets: statutory reserves and other reserves from profit (first indent of the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1), capital reserves (first indent of the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1), net profit and carried-forward profit (second indent of the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1), and the released amount of subscribed capital (first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1). The authority of the management to utilize released assets is limited as well, since the management is obligated to adhere to relevant statutory provisions and to the resolution of the general meeting (with regard to the latter, cf. Article 267 and the second paragraph of Article 285 in relation with Article 267 of ZGD-1). Both shareholders (pursuant to Article 233 of ZGD-1) and members of management or supervisory bodies (pursuant to Article 263 of ZGD-1) are liable for violating the payment ban. In case of a waiver of the obligation to provide contributions, the debt waiver agreement is null and void pursuant to the first paragraph of Article 86 of the Code of Obligations.32 4.2 Payment ban after the reduction of subscribed capital The ban stipulated by the first sentence of Article 380 of ZGD-1 enters into force when the simplified subscribed capital reduction becomes effective, i.e. when the resolution on capital reduction is registered in the court registry (third paragraph of Article 379 in relation with Article 374 27 Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 229, l. no. 4), including a presentation of possible occurrence of competition of creditors. 28 Cf. Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, § 230, l. no. 21). 29 Accord Plavšak in ZGD-1 (Kocbek et al., 2014, p. 440). 16 30 In future periods, the loss covered with the released amount of subscribed capital could otherwise be covered from profit (eleventh paragraph of Article 64 and first paragraph of Article 230 of ZGD-1). Cf. Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, § 230, l. no. 3). 31 Cf. Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, § 230, l. no. 3). 32 Code of Obligations (OZ), Official Journal of RS, No. 83/2001 with subsequent amendments and revisions. of ZGD-1). As of that moment, dividend payments are not admissible, and the company is not allowed to utilize distributable profit for other purposes stipulated by the corporate charter until the amount of statutory reserve-fund reaches the threshold stipulated by law or corporate charter. The share of subscribed capital to be reached by statutory reserve-fund is measured on grounds of the reduced subscribed capital. Until statutory reserve-fund has been filled, the provision of the fourth paragraph of Article 64, which stipulates a 5% restriction of the amount of net profit which may be reallocated to statutory reserves, does not apply (as per the second sentence of Article 380 of ZGD-1). The second sentence of Article 380 of ZGD-1 does not prescribe the obligation to set aside and reallocate statutory reserves, as the latter is still governed by the third and fourth paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1. The second sentence of Article 380 of ZGD-1 merely breaks through the 5% threshold stipulated by the fourth paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1. The fourth paragraph of Article 64, modified by the second sentence of Article 380 of ZGD-1, thus denotes the following: If necessary, the company shall reallocate to statutory reserves all net profit, reduced by the amount potentially required to cover the carried-forward loss, until statutory reserve-fund reaches the share of (the reduced) subscribed capital stipulated by law or corporate charter. The primary (and, to a certain extent, only) intent and purpose of Article 380 of ZGD-1 is the safeguarding of creditors, including future creditors.33 The institution allows for a quicker renouncement of the payment ban and is thus only of indirect benefit to the shareholders. The law calls for an accelerated filling of statutory reserves and protection of capital against (potential future) losses, as well as for the strengthening of capital after the simplified subscribed capital reduction becomes effective. The payment ban instituted by categories of tied-up capital is reduced through the reduction of subscribed capital and the covering of losses with assets made available by the capital reduction. If subscribed capital would not be subject to reduction, future profits would need to be utilized to cover the loss, i.e. to fill tied-up assets.34 It is for this very purpose that the law locks up future profits in the company, so that they need to be reallocated (in an accelerated manner) to the tied-up capital category (statutory reserves). By doing so, the law not only ties up the assets prior to the reduction of subscribed capital (second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1) and assets made available by capital reduction (first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1), but also the profits realized after the reduction of subscribed capital 33 In German law, cf. Veil in Schmidt/Lutter AktG (Schmidt et al., 2008, § 233, l. no. 1-2). 34 Cf. Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, § 233, l. no. 3). (Article 380 of ZGD-1). Dividend payments are not admissible and distributable profit shall not be utilized for other purposes stipulated by the corporate charter. Not only is the company allowed to reallocate a greater volume of net profit to statutory reserves, it is obligated to do so. Until statutory reserve-fund has been filled, distributable profit does not exist, since the entire net profit is channeled to statutory reserves. 4.3 In all cases and instances The situations referred to in the first indent of the second paragraph of Article 379 and the first sentence of Article 380 of ZGD-1 are related to the same qualifying element: filled statutory reserve-fund, the amount of which is measured on grounds of the new (reduced) amount of subscribed capital. The maximum amount of statutory reserves which may remain in order for simplified subscribed capital reduction to be admissible is equal to the minimum amount which allows a company to freely utilize distributable profit after the capital reduction becomes effective. Regardless of the intent and purpose (first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1) for which simplified subscribed capital reduction was executed, it may occur that the company will have full statutory reserve-fund available for disposal immediately after subscribed capital reduction becomes effective. It may also occur that the company will previously utilize even those tied-up reserves which it might had saved, meaning that statutory reserve-fund will not be full after the capital reduction. The application (effect) of Article 380 of ZGD-1 is thus not dependent on the purpose (first paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1) of simplified subscribed capital reduction, but rather on the level of filled capacity of statutory reserve-fund at the moment when capital reduction becomes effective. 5 Too Narrow and Too Broad at the Same Time To be precise, the previously referred to promotion of capital strength is only part of the truth, as the law simultaneously takes away some of the company's room for manoeuvre which it could have had without endangering its creditors. If Article 380 of ZGD-1 would not have the second sentence, the reallocation of statutory reserves would be governed only by the fourth paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1. Moreover, if the first sentence of Article 380 of ZGD-1 would not extend beyond the ban on payment of distributable profit to shareholders, the surplus net profit, i.e. the profit in excess of 5%, would be channeled to distributable profit, which could in turn be utilized for other purposes (stipulated by law or corporate charter), including the setting aside of statutory reserves (if so stipulated by the corporate charter), whereas the 5% threshold stipulated by the fourth paragraph of Article 64 is (most certainly) not relevant to the aforementioned situation.35 Distributable profit still couldn't be channeled to shareholders (until statutory reserve-fund has been filled), whereas the decision on accelerated protection and strengthening of capital by means of tied-up reserves would be left to shareholders, i.e. to those who are not entitled to distributable profit until the capital has been given adequate protection and reached adequate strength (as stipulated by law or corporate charter). If distributable profit would be classified as carried-forward profit, the latter would automatically be utilized to cover potential net loss (incurred in future fiscal periods). In case the general meeting decided to utilize distributable profit to set aside other reserves from profit (first sentence of the sixth paragraph of Article 230 of ZGD-1), the latter could (again) be utilized to cover the loss. In case of potential net loss, the carried-forward profit and other reserves from profit would even be the first to suffer. The same is true for corporate charter reserves36 if they are allowed to be utilized to cover the loss. Moreover, shareholders would be given the chance to directly influence subscribed capital even before statutory reserve-fund has been filled (and could do so to a much greater extent): distributable profit may be categorized as carried-forward profit, and the latter is an admissible source of increasing subscribed capital with company assets (fifth point of the first paragraph of Article 359 of ZGD-1). 35 Unlike the German AktG (third paragraph of § 58), ZGD-1 fails to stipulate that distributable profit may be utilized to set aside reserves from profit, but only limits the utilization of distributable profit to other reserves from profit (Liabilities and Equity A. III. 5.). According to the German AktG, distributable profit may, by law, be utilized to set aside additional statutory reserves. Per ZGD-1, the latter would be possible on grounds of appropriate corporate charter regulation. In the aforementioned instance, the general meeting would be able to decide on the reallocation of distributable profit to statutory reserves. The general meeting is also not obligated to adhere to the 5% threshold stipulated by the fourth paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1 when deciding on the amount of distributable profit to be reallocated. This allows for setting aside of statutory reserves prematurely and allows the company to reach the upper limit of the statutory reserve-fund threshold in an accelerated manner. The upper limit of statutory reserve-fund and the 5% allocation threshold are thus relevant only when reallocating statutory reserves from net profit with regard to the preparation and adoption of the annual report. However, the grounds for challenge stipulated by Article 399 of ZGD-1 need to be observed even in case of reallocation of statutory reserves as part of the utilization of distributable profit. For details on setting aside reserves from profit from distributable profit see Drnovšek (2010, p. 1502, 1519-1521). 36 Corporate charter reserves are the reserves referred to in the fourth indent of the second paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1 (Liabilities and Equity A. III. 4.). 5.1 Safeguarding of creditors that benefits shareholders Article 380 of ZGD-1 safeguards the creditors. Until statutory reserve-fund has been filled, the provision does not allow for any derogation and shareholders must simply accept the payment ban (the same applies to other potential beneficiaries of distributable profits, if they are entitled to receive payments pursuant to the corporate charter). However, this is where it all ends. Immediately after statutory reserve-fund has been filled, the full distributable profit may again be distributed among shareholders and utilized for other purposes stipulated by the corporate charter. As a matter of fact, it is now even easier to channel distributable profit from the company, since the threshold of the payment ban, set with categories of tied-up capital, mostly subscribed capital, has been lifted (reduced). The forgoing notwithstanding, the law fails to stipulate any additional safeguards to the filling of statutory reserve-fund, and even the amount of the latter is measured on grounds of the reduced subscribed capital. For clarity purposes and to help future analysis, let us consult the following typical example, referred to in the second paragraph of Article 379 of ZGD-1. In the example above, the company is able to execute a simplified subscribed capital reduction in order to cover the loss (- 250); however, it does not need to execute a prior release of tied-up reserves. After the subscribed capital reduction executed in order to cover the loss, the position is as shown in Table 2. Table 1 Position Prior to the Reduction of Subscribed Capital Assets Liabilities + Equity Subscribed capital 1,000 Capital reserves (points 1 through 3 of the first paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1) 30 Statutory reserves 45 Net profit/loss - 250 Liabilities 200 1,025 1,025 Table 2 Position After the Reduction of Subscribed Capital Assets Liabilities + Equity Subscribed capital 750 Capital reserves (points 1 through 3 of the first paragraph of Article 64 of ZGD-1) 30 Statutory reserves 45 Liabilities 200 1,025 1,025 After the subscribed capital reduction the payment ban is still instituted by tied-up capital categories (as well as foreign capital), however, the very amount of tied-up capital has been reduced (previously 1,075; now 825). In case the company would not cover the loss by executing a simplified subscribed capital reduction, it would first need to utilize future profit to cover the loss and fill statutory reserve-fund. The company would thus need to realize profit in excess of 275 (250 to cover the loss and an additional 25 to fill statutory reserve-fund). However, after covering the loss against subscribed capital, the company does not need to realize any additional profit, but is free to channel the entire new profit to shareholders (among others). Although the loss-affected assets of the company have not been changed (strengthened) with the reduction of subscribed capital, and the position of creditors has subsequently not been altered, it is still possible to channel all future profit away from the company. At this point, one needs to recall the fact that the main replacement for Article 375 of ZGD-1 with regard to simplified subscribed capital reduction is represented by the inadmissibility of channeling released assets to shareholders. However, as shown in the previous example, the situation is not far from what the law prohibits. The relevant amount of subscribed capital may not have been paid to the shareholders, however, the very reduction of subscribed capital allowed the company to cover the loss and simultaneously lower the payment ban, instituted by elements of tied-up capital, and thus achieve easier (quicker) channeling of distributable profit. command is undermined by the (next available) option to channel (excessive) profits away from the company after the reduction of subscribed capital.37 This gap is quite simple to bridge: the existing concept of safeguarding of creditors should be supplemented by introducing a time-limited ban on the payment of the majority of distributable profits, which would apply despite the fact that the statutory reserve-fund has been filled. Such a ban would give a company sufficient room for manoeuvre in strengthening its financial position in the future. A quantity-based parallel could be drawn by reference to Article 399 of ZGD-1 which stipulates that a 4% dividend is considered sufficient margin for the safeguarding of shareholders' interests.38 Article 380 of ZGD-1 thus needs to be amended so that a certain period of time (e.g., two fiscal years after the general meeting resolution) needs to pass before the majority of distributable profits (e.g., dividend in excess of 4 %) can be paid, even though the statutory reserve-fund had been filled. An exception to the rule may be justified only by the safeguarding of creditors, modelled after the safeguarding regime applied in ordinary subscribed capital reduction.39 6 Consequences of Violations An annual report violating Article 380 of ZGD-1 is null and void (first indent of the first paragraph of Article 401 of ZGD-1), as is a general meeting resolution on the utilization of distributable profit (third indent of Article 390 of ZGD-1). Both shareholders (pursuant to Article 233 of ZGD-1) and members of management and supervisory bodies (Article 263 of ZGD-1) are liable for violations of the payment ban. 7 Conclusion The forgoing analysis leads us to the following valid conclusion: the concept of safeguarding of creditors as referred to in Article 380 of ZGD-1 allows for a (completely legal) circumvention of rules governing the terms for admissibility of simplified subscribed capital reduction (Article 379 of ZGD-1). The amounts referred to in Article 379 of ZGD-1 are, in fact, utilized solely for recovery, however, this very 37 German law (§ 233 of the German AktG) therefore justifiably limits the amount of distributable profit payments for a full two years after the adoption of the resolution on simplified subscribed capital reduction even if statutory and capital reserves have been sufficiently filled. Legal theory emphasizes that this very restriction replaces the concept of safeguarding of creditors, which is applied to ordinary subscribed capital reduction. For details, see Oechsler in Münchener Kommentar (Goette et al., 2011, § 233, l. no. 2-3). Cf. Lutter in Kölner Kommentar (Zöllner et al., 1995, § 233, l. no. 3). 38 First paragraph of Article 399 of ZGD-1: "A general meeting's resolution on the appropriation of distributable profits may be challenged ... if the general meeting decides not to distribute the profits to the shareholders in the amount corresponding to at least 4% of the share capital, provided that, according to the due diligence principle, this is unnecessary given the circumstances in which the company operates." 39 In comparative law, such a solution is referred to in the second paragraph of § 233 of the German AktG: "[...] Die Zahlung eines Gewinnanteils von mehr als vier vom Hundert ist erst für ein Geschäftsjahr zulässig, das später als zwei Jahre nach der Beschlußfassung über die Kapitalherabsetzung beginnt. Dies gilt nicht, wenn die Gläubiger, deren Forderungen vor der Bekanntmachung der Eintragung des Beschlusses begründet worden waren, befriedigt oder sichergestellt sind, soweit sie sich binnen sechs Monaten nach der Bekanntmachung des Jahresabschlusses, auf Grund dessen die Gewinnverteilung beschlossen ist, zu diesem Zweck gemeldet haben. [...]". References 1. Bratina, B., Jovanovič, D., Podgorelec, P., & Primec, A. (2011). Pravo družb in gospodarsko pogodbeno pravo. Maribor: De Vesta. 2. Drnovšek, G. (2010). Zakonski rezervni sklad delniške družbe. Podjetje in delo, 8, 1498-1536. 3. Drnovšek, G. (2013). Redno zmanjšanje osnovnega kapitala delniške družbe: namen, znesek, izplačilna zapora in oblika izločenega premoženja. Podjetje in delo, 5, 736-750. 4. Drnovšek, G. (2012). Upnikova pravica do zavarovanja in registrska zapora pri rednem zmanjšanju osnovnega kapitala delniške družbe. Podjetje in delo, 8, 1670-1696. 5. Goette, W., Habersack, M., Oechsler, J., et al. (2011). Münchener Kommentar zum Aktiengesetz. München: Verlag C. H. Beck/Verlag Franz Vahlen. 6. Hoffmann-Becking, M., Krieger, G., et al. (2007). Münchener Handbuch des Gesellschaftsrechts. München: Verlag C. H. Beck. 7. Hüffer, U. (2010). Aktiengesetz. München: Verlag C. H. Beck. 8. Ivanjko, Š., Kocbek, M., & Prelič, S. (2009) Korporacijsko pravo: pravni položaj gospodarskih subjektov. Ljubljana: GV založba. 9. Kocbek, M., Plavšak, N., et al. (2014). Veliki komentar Zakona o gospodarskih družbah (ZGD-1). Ljubljana: IUS Software, GV Založba. 10. Kocbek, M. (2013). Poenostavljeno zmanjšanje osnovnega kapitala zaradi kritja izgube na podlagi vmesne bilance stanja. Podjetje in delo, 2, 358-361. 11. Kobal, A. (2007). Prikriti prenosi premoženja in prikrita izplačila dobička—davčno pravni vidik (Ph.D. dissertation). Maribor: Pravna fakulteta Univerze v Mariboru. 12. Podgorelec, P. (2006). Ohranjanje osnovnega kapitala pri d.o.o. (2006). Podjetje in delo, 8, 1669-1698. 13. Schmidt, K. (1982). Die sanierende Kapitalerhöhung im Recht der Aktiengesellschaft, GmbH und Personengesellschaft. Zeitschrift für Unternehmens- und Gesellschaftsrecht (ZGR), 3, 519-538. http://dx.doi.org/10.1515/zgre.1982.11.3.519 14. Schmidt, K., Lutter, M., Veil, R., et al. (2008). Aktiengesetz Kommentar. Köln: Verlag Dr. Otto Schmidt. 15. Wirth, G. (1996). Vereinfachte Kapitalherabsetzung zur Unternehmenssanierung: Zugleich eine Anmerkung zum Urteil des LG Dresden vom 15. 8. 1995 "Sachsenmilch AG." Der Betrieb (DB), 17, 867-872. 16. Zöllner, W., Lutter, M., et al. (1995). Kölner Kommentar zum Aktiengesetz. Köln, Berlin, Bonn, München: Carl Heymanns Verlag KG. Author Gregor Drnovšek successfully defended his Ph.D. thesis in corporate law in January 2015 at the Faculty of Law in Maribor, where he was appointed to an assistant position. In addition, he has acquired more than 10 years of experience in economy, especially in banking, where he specialized in investment banking and corporate finance and served as executive secretary of a management board. He is the author of various original scientific articles and professional articles as well as co-author of monographs. In addition, he has participated in scientific conferences. His research and studies focus mainly on corporate law and takeover law. Varstvo upnikov pri poenostavljenem zmanjšanju osnovnega kapitala Izvleček Osrednji značilnosti poenostavljenega zmanjšanja osnovnega kapitala sta zelo ozek namen in oslabljeno varstvo upnikov. Namen je pravzaprav le en, namreč sanacija. Od finančno prizadete družbe je težko pričakovati, da bo pri zmanjšanju osnovnega kapitala, ki je namenjeno sanaciji, sposobna varovati upnike po merilih, ki veljajo pri rednem zmanjšanju osnovnega kapitala. V prispevku avtor analizira namen poenostavljenega zmanjšanja osnovnega kapitala in zakonsko ureditev varstva upnikov. Pri tem z metodo deskripcije, vsebinsko analizo in primerjalnopravno študijo utemelji, zakaj je pravna ureditev varstva upnikov prešibka glede na učinke te oblike zmanjšanja osnovnega kapitala, in predlaga spremembo zakonske ureditve. Ključne besede: poenostavljeno zmanjšanje osnovnega kapitala, varstvo upnikov, podbilanciranost, izplačilna prepoved, vezanost premoženja Is Trust in Banks in SLovenia Put to the Test? Sabina Taškar Beloglavec University of Maribor, FacuLty of Economics and Business Maribor, SLovenia sabina.beLogLavec@um.si Urban Šebjan University of Maribor, FacuLty of Economics and Business Maribor, SLovenia urban.sebjan@um.si Abstract The question of the banking system's stabiLity in connection to trust since the 2008 crisis has been the subject of many debates seeking to find permanent soLutions to banking system probLems, as the current situation affects bank customers' behavior. This article examined trust in banks during the financial crisis and offers, via demographic variabLes, expLanations as tow whether or not customers tend to withdraw their deposits during a crisis. The resuLts contribute to banks' decision-making regarding deposits management and understanding customers' behavior, especiaLLy during a crisis. The resuLts show a negative reLationship between trust and deposit withdrawaL intention, where gender and education LeveL pLay an important roLe. Keywords: trust, financial institution, bank, Slovenia, logistic regression 1 Introduction This article deals with trust. In economics, trust is the main factor allowing the fractional reserve bank system to exist and is the most important characteristic in the relationship between financial institutions, including banks, and their customers. Bank customers have a tendency to buy banking services from a bank, which they consider to be trustworthy and sound. This already fragile connection is under a lot of pressure in normal circumstances, let alone during times of crisis, when banks are often held responsible (Hurlburt, Miller & Voas, 2009; Schelkle, 2011). However, the complexity of the phenomenon itself is shown by the fact that trust has not only been examined in economics, but also by psychologists, sociologists, anthropologists, and others (for example, see Mayer, 2004; Whitney, 1994). One angle is common to all: the fragility of trust. Trust is gradually built, but can be destroyed in a moment (more for example Rempel, Holmes & Zanna, 1985; Weber, Malhotra & Murnighan, 2004). Authors also talk about trust's antipode—namely, mistrust (Tyler & Stanley, 2007)—and the perceived fairness of bank services (Szykman, Rahtz, & Plater, 2005). It is important to research and, in practice, implement trustworthy relationships because trust is a central concept on which other concepts, like loyalty and satisfaction (see Anderson & Narus, 1990) are based. These are a sustainable source of banks' competitive advantage (see Trif, 2013). Taking all these facts into consideration, it is necessary to research trust in banking systems. Therefore, our research deals with the relationship of trust, deposit safety scheme, and deposit withdrawals during times of financial crisis ORIGINAL SCIENTIFIC PAPER RECEIVED: MARCH 2015 REVISED: MAY 2015 ACCEPTED: MAY 2015 DOI: 10.1515/ngoe-2015-0012 UDK: 336.71:330.4(497.4) JEL: G01, G02, G21 NG NASE GOSPODARSTVO OUR ECONOMY VoL. . 61 No. 3 2015 pp. 41-50 in the case of the Slovenian banking system. We connected these variables with selected socioeconomic factors. The article continues as follows. We start with a theoretical background. AS this is an empirically oriented study, we test the conceptual model and three main hypotheses regarding (1) the impact of gender, age, and level of education of bank customers on their perceived bank deposit safety; (2) the impact of those factors on customers' perceived trust in the bank; and (3) the withdrawal of bank deposits connected to gender, age, and education. The third section of the article gives the research framework and delivers results. In the discussion and conclusion section, we assess the findings and give some suggestions for further research. 2 Literature Review This literature review deals with trust, connecting it to other variables that we considered in our research. In the following paragraphs, we summarize the limited literature on trust as a concept in the financial markets context, with financial institutions being the foundation of that part of the economy. We then discuss trust in connection with gender, age, and education level. The financial crisis and its consequences for all levels of economy and society offer a sound reason to also define trust through the optics of its resilience during a financial crisis, when it is tested over and over again in the relationship between banks and customers. In addition, banks are burdened with the process of restructuring and are even subject to failures. Customers seem to have different attitudes toward these processes, ranging from fear to understanding. The following section of the article is structured based on the research model depicted in Figure 1. This model incorporated concepts dealt with in the literature review; the hypotheses are presented and tested in the empirical part of the article. Figure 1: Conceptual research model 2.1 Concept of trust in financial institutions The body of literature in this field is mainly dedicated to banks rather than other financial institutions, which is probably due to the specifics of a bank as a company and its influence on the individual (Süchting, 1998). Trust is the most important category in the process of reaching a personal financial decision. As with all other services, banking services are intangible products and defined only by contract, which remove trust and make taking risks meaningless (Calderon, Chong, & Galindo, 2009; Sapienza & Zingales, 2009). Moorman, Deshpandé, and Zaltman (1992) defined trust as preparedness to relate to a trustworthy partner in the broadest meaning of the word, while Coulter and Coulter (2002) added that a higher level of trust leads to better cooperation. Authors in general tend to define trust as a dynamic category, resulting from a process, and talk about different dimensions of trust. Therefore, it can be defined through different viewpoints. As McKnight & Chervany (2000) pointed out, trust can be seen as a notion, as systemic trust, as belief, and an intention to trust (Sztompka, 1999), where it develops from a quality relationship (Whitney, 1994) over individual characteristics to a cultural standard. Therefore, bank customers and banks have built systemic trust, which is theoretically defined as trust between an institution and an individual. Customers tend to perceive the banking institution as a relationship to a system as a whole (Bennet & Kottasz, 2012); here, trust built between the customer and an individual banking clerk is in the foreground and an important basis for bank customer loyalty (Gulati, 1995; Parkhe, 1993; Zineldin, 1995). Trust is accompanied by other similar concepts, like loyalty and satisfaction that are interconnected and decisive in preserving the role of an individual bank as a customer's main bank. Despite the fact that individuals' subjective impression plays a leading role in defining what loyalty or satisfaction might be, trust and reliability are of great H Gender, age, level of education H2b 1 1 Bank deposit safety in times of crisis H Trust in banks in times of crisis H Withdrawal of funds in times of crisis Source: Authors importance in building and preserving customer loyalty (Bloemer, de Ruyter, & Peeters, 1998) Morgan and Hunt (1994) incorporated the concept of commitment into their model and defined it as a key element of banks' customer relations strategy. A long-term relationship has a positive relationship to trust while a bad image has a negative relationship to trust. However, trust needs a wider context than the bank-bank clerk-bank customer communication triangle to exist. It needs an operating, stable institutional framework (Aghion, Algan, Cahuc & Shleifer, 2010); Carlin, Dorobantu, & Viswanathan, 2009) and, consequently, a stable banking system given the regulatory and legislative demands. Stevenson and Wolfers (2011) argue that the level of trust in this connection depends on the country's development stage. In an international comparison (Coupé, 2011) of transition countries in Slovenia, 55% of respondents declared having trust in their banks. In the highly developed Netherlands (90%) or Austria (70%), the percentage is of course higher (Knell & Stix, 2010; Mosch & Prast, 2010), while for example in Bulgaria that level is significantly lower (Mudd & Valev, 2009). 2.2 Trust and financial crisis Trust, being a dynamic factor, changes over time. Stevenson and Wolfers (2011) demonstrated that changes in trust are connected with unemployment rate changes, which is quite a good predictor for future crises connected to bank deposit withdrawal (Guiso, Sapienza, & Zingales, 2008; Ramirez, 2009; Sapienza & Zingales, 2009). Deb and Chavali (2010) argued that the intention to deposit money is positively related to trust both pre- and post-crisis. During our literature review, we did not come upon any research dealing with trust in connection to the views and demographic characteristics of bank customers in Slovenia, as addressed to in this article. Various public polls have been conducted in this regard in Slovenia, and the results were published in mass media (see Delo, 2013; Slovenske novice, 2012). Interestingly, regardless of events in Spain and Greece, 71% of Slovenians have not thought about withdrawing their deposits (Slovenske novice, 2012). Bank runs did not occur in our banking system, although the financial crisis affected the amount of savings deposited in banks as 60.9% of respondents had lower savings than before the crisis (Slovenske novice, 2012). Vox populi research in 2012 found contradicting results: Half of respondents worried about their savings in banks, while 27% thought that their deposits were no longer safe (Delo, 2013). 2.3 The impact of gender, age, and education on trust Existing research on trust in the economic or business sense of the word has found that women have more troubles with trust in general (Alesina & La Ferrara, 2002). As consumers, women give more second thoughts to trust than men (Sheehan Bartel, 1999). Buchan, Croson, and Solnick (2008), in their research of behavioral differences in the investment game, discovered that men trust more than women, but women tend to be more trustworthy. Regarding the influence of educational level on trust, the literature is relatively scarce. When it comes to dealing with trust within the economic context and in the field of financial institutions and/or banks, it is even scarcer. However, based on the research in Mexico, which examined numerous factors affecting the relationship, it has been argued that people with less education feel uncomfortable with banking issues (Djankov, Miranda, Seira, & Sharma, 2008). Although the study focuses on a less developed banking system, this example is nevertheless a good example of the complexity involved in researching the bank-customer relationship. Many possible angles have to be considered, such as present customers' needs, future needs, retaining customers, and differences in the banking system's development level. Thus, the current paper provides insights into the relationship of trust based on selected demographic variables and between various trust viewpoints and circumstances, as defined in the conceptual research model. 3 Research 3.1 Research methodology 3.1.1 Sample and data collection A questionnaire was used to collect data from December 10, 2013, to January 27, 2014. The target population represented random users, over the age of 18, who were legally able to buy bank services in Slovenia independently. All the returned questionnaires were correctly completed. For the hypothesis testing, the data was collected based on a convenience non-random sample of 150 customers of bank services from Slovenia. In the total sample, 57% were male (n = 64) and 43% female (n = 86) respondents. A more detailed sample description is given in Table 1. Table 1 Sample Survey Results Control variables fi fi % Education: Less than secondary education 13 8.7 % Secondary education 53 35.3% More than secondary education 84 56.0% Gender: Male 64 57.3 % Female 86 42.7% Age: 18-28 years (young population) 59 39.3 % 29-39 years (middle population) 34 22.7 % More than 40 years (older population) 57 38.0 % Source: Authors' calculations The time of period was chosen deliberately due to the fact that some significant changes occurred in the Slovenian banking system at that time. Two main events in the banking sector took place: The ownership structure changed due to the Slovenian government's recapitalization of five banks, and the banking system's restructuring process began with the supervised liquidation of two private banks, Factor Banka and Probanka. Non-performing assets were then transferred to the Bank Assets Management Company, established in March 2013 (BAMC, 2015; BS, 2015). Such events were so powerful and present in day-to-day media that they were expected to make the public think about the banking crises even more and put their trust in banks to the test. 3.1.2 Instrument of research The theoretical framework and conceptual research model served to develop questions to study three variables: bank deposit safety, trust in banks during a crisis, and withdrawal of savings during a crisis. Demographic characteristics were also considered. The bank deposit safety variable was measured with yes (1) or no (0) answers to a question about whether individuals considered their deposits to be safe in banks. Trust in the bank was measured with the same di-chotomous answers to a question about trust in one's bank in times of crisis. Finally, the withdrawal of savings in times of crisis also used the same dichotomous answers to a question about whether individuals would in times of financial crisis withdraw their bank deposits. Three control variables were included in the questionnaire to check if hypothesized predictor variables affected bank deposit safety, trust in banks in times of crisis, and withdrawal of savings in times of crisis beyond the impact of these variables. The control variables were age (categorical variable: young population from 18 to 28, middle-aged population from 29 to 39, and older population over 40 years of age), gender (dichotomous variable: females were assigned value 0 and males value 1), and education (categorical variable: less than secondary education, secondary education, and post-secondary education). 3.1.3 Data analysis We formally tested three hypotheses: • H^ Bank customers' gender, age, and level of education affect their perceived bank deposit safety in times of crisis. • H2: Bank customers' perceived bank deposit safety in times of crisis, gender, age, and education have a significant effect on their perceived trust in the bank in times of crisis. • H3: Customers' perceived trust in the bank in times of crisis, gender, age, and level of education play a significant role in the decision to withdraw funds from their savings account in times of crisis. We used binomial logistic regression (Hosmer & Lemeshow, 2000; Kedmenec, Tominc, & Rebernik, 2014), which estimates the probability of an event—in our case, the recognition of opportunities or not. We ran five binomial logistic regressions. While Model I includes only control variables, Models II, III, IV, and V include both the predictor variables and control variables. The parameters of the logistic response functions were estimated using the maximum likelihood method, which denotes changes in the log odds of the independent variable. In logistic regression, the observed and predicted values can be used to assess the fit of the model. The measure we use is the log-likelihood based on summing the probabilities associated with the predicted and actual outcomes (Field, 2009, p. 267): Log-likelihood = Sili[YiIn(P(Yj)) + (1 - Yj)In(l - P(Yj))] (1) To test whether the relationship between dependent and independent variables is direct or indirect, binary logistic regression was used to develop a model as follows: P(Y) = e-(bo+biXli+b2XZj+ —+ibnXni> (2) where: P(Y) is the probability of the dependent variable (Model I: bank deposit safety in times of crisis; Models II and III: trust in banks during a crisis; Models IV and V: withdrawal of savings in times of crisis) b0 = a constant b. = the estimated coefficients X. = the independent variables e = the base of the natural logarithm In order to test whether the inclusion of predictor variables led to statistically significant improvements of the model, we used the Blok x2-test. We computed the improvement of the model as follows: The goodness of fit of the model was assessed using the Model x2-test, the rate of correct classifications, Nagelkerke's (1991) Щ, Cox and Snell's (1989) R2CS, and Hosmer and Le-meshow's (2000) RH : Rjj -- Rcs [2(LL(baseline)l (3) x2 = 2[LL(new) - LL(baseline)], (df = kew - ^J (8) where x2 is the chi-square distribution, df is degrees of freedom, and к is number of parameters. The 0.05 (two-tailed) significance level was used. To test the hypotheses, it was appropriate to use SPSS 21 software. _ j _ e[~(LL(new))-(LL(baseline))] RS -2LL (model) -2LL (original) (4) (5) where LL is log-likelihood and n is sample size. Hair, Anderson, Tatham, and Black (1998) argued that Cox and Snell's RfS is reported less frequently because it cannot reach the maximum value of 1. In order to test the significance of the regression coefficient, we used the Wald statistic, which is "usually used to ascertain whether a variable is a significant predictor of the outcome" (Field, 2009, p. 270): Wald = --— SEb (6) where b is the regression coefficient and SEb the standard error. .CS , and Nagelkerke's R^ The Wald statistic, Cox and Snell's Rf are statistical tools used to test the effectiveness of a model by looking at whether a model fits the data (Seo, Ranganathan, & Babad, 2008). We also measured the value of the odds ratio (Exp(ß), which is an indicator of the change in odds resulting from a unit change in the predictor. "The odds of an event occurring are defined as the probability of an event occurring divided by the probability of that event not occurring" (Field, 2009, p. 271). We can calculate the odds as: 0ddS = P (ncTevent)' ^^ = ^-(bUiXÜ» P(no event Y) = 1 - P(event Y) P(Y) = the probability of Y occurring e = base of natural logarithms b0 = constant bn = coefficient (or weight) attached to predictor Xn = predictor variable 3.2 Results In Model I in Table 2, bank deposit safety in times of crisis is the dependent variable and demographic factors are the control variables. It can be seen that only gender and age are significant at the 0.05 level (Model x2 = 30.267, p < 0.001). Table 2 Results of Logistic Regressions-Model I (Bank deposit safety in times of crisis (PBAD); 0-no, 1-yes) Variables Variable Model I categories Coeff. ß Wald Exp(ß) S.E. Gender 0-female 1.193" 8.943 3.296 1-male (0.399) Age Young -1.377* 4.638 0.252 population (0.640) Middle -0.174- 0.084 0.841 population (0.598) Older bc- population Education Less than -1.438- 3.474 0.237 secondary (0.772) Secondary 0.370ns- 0.681 1.448 degree (0.449) More than Secondary bc- Constant 0.652 1.419 1.919 (0.547) Model X2 (df) 30.267" (5) Block X2 (df) -2LL (final model) 169.903 (7) Nagelkerke R 0.248 Cox & Snell Щ 0.183 X2 Hosmer and Lemeshow's RfL 28.064" % of correct predictions 72.0 Notes: *** significant at p < 0.001; ** significant at p < 0.01; * significant at p < 0.05; n s' not significant; b,c base category Source: Authors' calculations. The relationship between gender and bank deposit safety in times of crisis is significant (ß = 1.193, p < 0.01), indicating that male customers are more likely to perceive bank deposit safety in times of crisis compared to female ones. We also found that the younger population is less likely than the older population to perceive bank deposit safety in times of crisis (ß = -1.377, p < 0.05), indicating that Hypothesis 1 can only be partially accepted. Nagelkerke's Щ is a further modification of the Cox and Snell coefficient Щ5 to ensure that it can vary from 0 to 1 (Nagelkerke, 1991). For the model estimates, Cox and Snell's R2S and Nagelkerke's Щ measures are 0.183 and 0.248, respectively, which confirm the statistical robustness of the estimated results. Hosmer and Lemeshaw's R^_L test (X2 = 28.064; df = 7; p < 0.001) indicated that the predicted model fits well with the data. From Table 3, it can be seen that Model III, which includes both predictor and control variables, is significant at the 0.001 level (Model x2 = 99.285, p < 0.001). As Block x2 is also significant (Block X2 = 27.646, p < 0.001), the inclusion of predictor variables into the model leads to significant improvement of the model compared to Model II. Bank deposit safety significantly predicts (Wald = 34.799, p < 0.001) the odds of trust in banks in times of crisis. In Model III, the relationship between bank deposit safety and trust in banks in times of crisis is significant (ß = 4.551, p < 0.001), indicating that those customers who perceive bank deposit safety in times of crisis are more likely to have trust in banks in times of crisis. Gender significantly predicts (Wald = 5.279, p < 0.05) the odds of trust in banks in times of crisis. Male customers are less likely to perceive trust in banks in times of crisis (ß = -1.417, p < 0.001) than female customers. Table 3 Results of Logistic Regressions-Models II and III (Trust in banks in times of crisis (TB); 0-no, 1-yes) Variables Variable Model II Model III categories Coeff. ß S.E. Wald Exp(ß) Coeff. ß S.E. Wald Exp(ß) Bank deposit safety in the crisis time 0-no 1-yes 3.317''' (0.466) 50.662 27.574 4.551''' (0.772) 34.799 94.770 Gender Age 0-female 1-male Young population Middle population Older bc-population -1.417' (0.617) -0.151- (0.809) 1.937' (0.699) 5.279 0.035 7.687 0.242 0.860 6.937 Education Less than secondary Secondary degree More than Secondary b. c. 0.632 ns. (1.683) 2.340'' (0.683) 0.141 11.739 1.881 10.379 Constant -1.833 (0.381) -3.848 (0.874) Model X2 (df) 71.640''' (1) 99.285''' (6) Block X2 (df) 27.646''' (5) -2LL (initial model) -2LL (final model) 134.595 106.949 R2 79.5 Nagelkerke RN 0.508 0.648 Cox & Snell R2CS 0.484 X2 Hosmer and Lemeshow's RHL 3.346 ns. % of correct predictions 83.3 83.3 Notes: *** significant at p < 0.001; ** significant at p < 0.01; * significant at p < 0.05; n,s- not significant; b,c base category; = 1 - [2LL (final model) / - 2LL (initial model)] Source: Authors' calculations. The relationship between age and trust in banks in times of crisis is significant (ß = 1.937, p < 0.05), indicating that middle-aged adults are more likely to perceive trust in banks in times of crisis than the older population. This means that Hypothesis 2 was partly proven. Educational attainment is also significant, having a positive effect (ß = 2.340, p < 0.01) on trust in banks in times of crisis. We also found that customers with a secondary degree are more likely to perceive trust in banks in times of crisis than those with a post-secondary degree. The R2 model equaled 79.5%, which means that 79.5% of the variation in the dependent variable is explained by the model. The current model's Nagelkerke's RN is 0.648, which is fairly high, suggesting a good fit for the model. The predictive power of the model is very good, with an overall accuracy of 83.3%. Table 4 summarizes the results of the binary logistic regression for Models IV and V. One predictor variable and three control variables were included in Model V. Trust in banks in times of crisis was included in Model IV; gender, age, and education were included in Model V. As the Block x2 is also significant (Block x2 = 48.609, p < 0.001), the inclusion of control variables in the model leads to a significant improvement of the model compared to Model V. It accounted for 27.7% (Cox and Snell's R^) to 37.2% (Nagelkerke's RN) of the variance in withdrawals of savings in times of crisis. The result of the Hosmer and Lemeshow test R^_L was significant (x2 = 23.0; df = 8; p < 0.01), indicating that the model was good and the data fit the model well. This model correctly classified 76.7% of rates. The Ri model equaled 84.6%, which means that 84.6% of the variation in the dependent variable is explained by the model. Table 4 Results of Logistic Regressions-Models IV and V (Withdrawal of savings in times of crisis (SW); 0-no, 1-yes) Variables Variable Model IV Model V categories Coeff. ß S.E. Wald Exp(ß) Coeff. ß S.E. Wald Exp(ß) Trust in banks in crisis time 0-no 1-yes -1.539''' (0.354) 18.840 0.215 -2.416''' (0.501) 23.254 0.089 Gender Age 0-female 1-male Young population Middle population Older bc population -1.272'' (0.416) 0.503ns. (0.670) 1.248 ns. (0.668) 9.337 0.564 3.494 0.280 1.654 3.482 Education Less than secondary Secondary degree More than Secondary b. c. 0.279 ns. (0.709) 1.941''' (0.539) 0.154 12.970 1.321 6.966 Constant 0.519 (0.253) 4.218 1.680 -0.006 (0.602) 0.000 0.994 Model X2 (df) 20.190''' (1) 48.609''' (6) Block X2 (df) 28.419''' (5) -2LL (initial model) -2LL (final model) 184.516 156.097 R2 84.6 Nagelkerke RN 0.169 0.372 Cox & Snell R2CS 0.277 X2 Hosmer and Lemeshow's Ri , ^ H-L 23.0'' % of correct predictions 68.7 76.7 Notes: *** significant at p < 0.001; ** significant at p < 0.01; * significant at p < 0.05; ns' not significant; b,c base category; = 1 - [2LL (final model) / - 2LL(initial model)] Source: Authors' calculations. The results of the main Model V (Table 4) show that trust in banks in times of crisis is associated with a higher likelihood of withdrawal of funds from bank accounts in times of crisis (ß = -2.416, p < 0.001). This result explains that those customers who trust in their bank during a crisis are perceived to be less likely to withdraw their savings in times of crisis. Gender is also significant, having a negative effect (ß = -1.272, p < 0.01) on withdrawal of savings in times of crisis. Males are less likely to perceive the need to withdraw money in times of crisis than females. The results also indicate that no significant relationship exists between age and withdrawal of funds in times of crisis. Finally, the level of education presents a positive, significant sign (ß = 1.941, p < 0.001), indicating that those with a secondary degree perceive are more likely to withdraw money in times of crisis than those with a post-secondary degree. These results partially support Hypothesis 3. 4 Discussion and Conclusions In this study, we used a conceptual research model to study the behavior of bank customers in times of crisis. We found a link between bank customers' gender and age and bank deposit safety in times of crisis. Our research results show that male customers are on average 3.3 times more likely to perceive bank deposit safety in times of crisis than female customers (Exp (ß) = 3.296). In addition, the younger population is on average only 0.3 times less likely to perceive bank deposit safety in times of crisis than the older population (Exp (ß) = 0252). From these results, it can be concluded that female customers are more cautious than males about perceived bank deposit safety in times of crisis. The younger population also perceives less bank deposit safety in times of crisis than the older population. The reasons for such results could be the lack of both experience and insight into banks' operating models in younger customers. The results showed no significant correlation between customers' level of education and bank deposit safety in times of crisis. In the next phase, we examined the relationship between bank deposit safety in times of crisis, demographic factors, and trust in banks in times of crisis. We found that individuals who perceive bank deposit safety in times of crisis are on average only 94.7 times as likely to trust in banks in times of crisis as those who do not perceive bank deposit safety in times of crisis (Exp (ß) = 94.770). We also focused on the influence of confidence in banks during a crisis and the impact of demographic factors on the withdrawal of money from a savings account in times of crisis. Customers who trust banks in times of crisis are on average only 0.1 times less likely to withdraw their savings during a crisis than those who do not trust banks in times of crisis ((Exp (ß) = 0.089). Thus, banks have to continually invest resources in maintaining their customers' trust to be able to maintain an adequate level of savings in their customers' bank accounts. This study could be expanded to include other factors, such as the reliability of banks and trust in deposit schemes in times of crisis, as well as additional demographic factors (income, status). The study could also be extended to other comparable geographic markets. It is important to note that the bank customers were asked only about the possible decisions in times of crisis, but this might not necessarily reflect their concrete decisions and actions in times of crisis. References 1. Aghion, P., Algan, Y., Cahuc, P., & Shleifer, A. (2010). Regulation and Distress. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, MIT Press, vol. 125(3), pages 1015-1049. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2010.125.3.1015 2. Alesina, A., & La Ferrara, E. (2002). Who trusts others? Journal of Public Economics, 85(2), 207-234. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/ S0047-2727(01)00084-6 3. Anderson, J. C., & Narus, J. A. (1990). A model of distributor firm and manufacturer firm working partnerships. The Journal of Marketing, 54(1), 42-58. 4. BAMC. (2015). BAMC started the third asset transfer phase, transferring the assets of 92 companies. Retrieved from http://www.dutb.eu/ en/for-the-media/press-releases/61-dutb-jje-zacela-tretjjo-fazo-prenosa-terjjatev-v-kateri-so-terjatve-do-92-tih-podjjetijj 5. Banka Slovenije (BS). (2014). Financial stability review, March 2014. Retrieved from https://www.bsi.si/en/publications.asp?MapaId=784 6. Bennett, R., & Kottasz, R. (2012). Public attitudes towards the UK banking industry following the global financial crisis. The International Journal of Bank Marketing, 30(2), 128-147. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/02652321211210877 7. Bloemer J., de Ruyter, K., & Peeters, P. (1998). Investigating drivers of bank loyalty: the complex relationship between image, service quality and satisfaction. International Journal of Bank Marketing, 16(7), 276-286. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/02652329810245984 8. Buchan, N. R., Croson, R. T., & Solnick, S. (2008). Trust and gender: An examination of behavior and beliefs in the Investment Game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68(3), 466-476. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2007.10.006 9. Calderon, C., Chong, A., & GaLindo, A. (2002). Development and efficiency of the financial sector and links with trust: Cross-country evidence. Economic Development and Cultural Change. 51(1), 189-204. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/344547 10. Carlin, B. I., Dorobantu, F., & Viswanathan, S. (2009). Public trust, the law, and financial investment. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3), 321-341. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jjfineco.2008.07.001 11. Coulter, K. S., & Coulter, R. A. (2002). Determinants of trust in a service provider: the moderating role of length of relationship. Journal of Service Marketing 16(1), 35-50. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/08876040210419406 12. Coupé, T. (2011). Mattresses versus banks—The effect of trust on portfolio composition. Kyiv School of Economics and Kyiv Economics Institute Discussion Paper No. 40. 13. Cox, D. R., & Snell, E. J. (1989). The analysis of binary data (2nd ed.). London: Chapman & Hall. 14. Deb, M., & Chavali, K. (2010). Significance of trust and loyalty during financial crisis: A study on customer behavior of Indian banks. South Asian Journal of Management, 17(1), 43-60. 15. Delo. (2013). Anketa dela: Še zadostno zaupanje v banke. Retrieved from http://www.delo.si/novice/politika/anketa-dela-se-zadost-no-zaupanje-v-banke.html 16. Djankov, S., Miranda, P., Seira, E., & Sharma, S. (2008). Who are the unbanked?World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS4647. 17. Field, A. (2009). Discovering statistics using SPSS (3rd ed.). London: Sage. 18. Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Trusting the stock market.Journal of Finance, 63(6), 2557-2600. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/ j.1540-6261.2008.01408.x 19. Gulati, R. (1995). Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual choices in alliances. Academy of Management Journal, 38(1), 85-112. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/256729 20. Hair, J., Anderson, R., Tatham, R., & Black, W. (1998). Multivariate data analysis. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall International. 21. Hosmer, D. W., & Lemeshow, S. (2000). Applied logistic regression (2nd ed.). New York: Wiley. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/0471722146 22. Hurlburt, G. F., Miller, K. W., & Voas, J. M. (2009). An ethical analysis of automation, risk, and the financial crises of 2008. IT Professional Magazine, 11(1), 14-19. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/MITP.2009.2 23. Kedmenec, I., Tominc, P., & Rebernik, M. (2014). Gender differences in the usage of resources in the entrepreneurial opportunity identification process in Slovenia and Croatia. Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 27(1), 366-377. http://dx.doi.org/10.10 80/1331677X.2014.966973 24. Knell, M., & Stix, H. (2010). Trust in nanks—Evidence from normal times and from times of crises. Beiträge zur Jahrestagung des Vereins für Socialpolitik 2010: Ökonomie der Familie-Session: Trusting Banks in a Financial Crisis, No. A1-V1. 25. Mayer, J. (2004). Zaupanje kot pogoj za ustvarjalno sodelovanje. In: Rozman R. & Kovač, J. (Eds.): Zaupanje v in med organizacijami (združbami). Kranj: Fakulteta za organizacijske vede, Ekonomska fakulteta, Zveza organizatorjev Slovenije. 26. McKnight, D. H., & Chervany, N. L. (2001). Trust and distrust definitions: One bite at a time. In: Falcone, R., Singh, M. & Tan, Y.-H. (Eds.): Trust in Cyber-societies. LNAI 2246, 27-54, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg. 27. Moorman, C., Deshpandé, R., & Zaltman, G. (1992). Relationships between providers and users of market research: the dynamics of trust within and between organizations. Journal of Marketing Research, 29(3), 314-329. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3172742 28. Morgan, R. M., & Hunt, S. D. (1994). The commitment trust theory of relationship marketing. Journal of Marketing, 58(3), 20-38. http:// dx.doi.org/10.2307/1252308 29. Mosch, R., & Prast, H. (2010). Confidence and trust: empirical investigations for the Netherlands and the financial sector. Beiträge zur Jahrestagung des Vereins für Socialpolitik 2010: Ökonomie der Familie-Session: Trusting Banks in a Financial Crisis, No. A1-V2 30. Mudd, S. B., & Valev, N. T. (2009). Once bitten, twice shy: experiences of a banking crisis and expectations of future crises. Wiliam Davidson Institute Working paper. No.969. Retrieved from http://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/handle/2027.42/64382/wp969. pdf?sequence=1 http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1490072 31. Nagelkerke, N. (1991). A note on a general definition of the coefficient of determination. Biometrika, 78(3), 691-692. http://dx.doi. org/10.1093/biomet/78.3.691 32. Parkhe, A. (1993). Strategic alliances structuring: a game theoretic and transaction cost examination of inter-firm cooperation. Academy of Management Journal, 36(4), 739-794. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/256759 33. Ramirez, C. (2009). Bank fragility, "money under the mattress," and long-run growth: U.S. evidence from the "perfect" panic of 1893. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33(12), 2185-2198. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.05.020 34. Rempel, J. K., Holmes, J. G., & Zanna, M. P. (1985). Trust in close relationships. Journal of personality and social psychology, 49(1), 95. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.49.1.95 35. Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2009). A trust crisis. Retrieved from http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/brian.barry/igm/atrustcrisis.pdf 36. Schelkle, W. (2011). A tale of two crises: The euro area in 2008/09 and in 2010. European Political Science:EPS, 10(3), 375-383. http:// dx.doi.org/10.1057/eps.2011.23 37. Seo, D. B., Ranganathan, C., & Babad, Y. (2008). Two-level model of customer retention in the US mobile telecommunications service market. Telecommunications Policy, 32, 182-196. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j~.telpol.2007.09.004 38. Sheehan Bartel, K. (1999). An investigation of gender differences in on-line privacy concerns and resultant behaviors. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 13(4), 24-38. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1520-6653(199923)13:4<24::AID-DIR3>3.0.C0;2-0 39. Slovenske novice. (2012). Vse težje je kaj privarčevati, a bankam (še) zaupamo. Retrieved from http://www.slovenskenovice.si/novice/ slovenija/vse-tezje-je-kaj-privarcevati-bankam-se-zaupamo 40. Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2011). Trust in public institutions over the business cycle. IZZA Discussion Paper No. 5570. http://dx.doi. org/10.2139/ssrn.1787737 41. Süchting, J. (1998). Die Theorie der Bankloyalität-(immer noch) eine Basis zum Verständnis der Absatzbeziehungen von Kreditinstituten?. In Handbuch des Bankmarketing (pp. 1-25). Wiesbaden: Gabler Verlag. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-322-93179-5_1 42. Sztompka, P. (1999). Trust: A sociological theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 43. Szykman, L., Rahtz, D. R., & Plater, M. (2005). Living on the edge: financial services for the lower socio-economic strata. Discourse, Diversity and Distinction: Macromarketing at 30 Years, 59. 44. Trif, S. M. (2013). The influence of overall satisfaction and trust on customer loyalty. Management & Marketing, S(1), 109. 45. Tyler, K., & Stanley, E. (2007). The role of trust in financial services business relationships. Journal of Services Marketing, 21(5), 334-344. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/08876040710773642 46. Weber, J. M., Malhotra, D., & Murnighan, J. K. (2004). Normal acts of irrational trust: Motivated attributions and the trust development process. Research in organizational behavior, 26, 75-101. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0191-3085(04)26003-8 47. Whitney, J. O. (1994). The trust factor: Liberating profits and restoring corporate vitality. New York: McGraw-Hall, Inc. 48. Zineldin, M. (1995). Bank-company interactions and relationships: some empirical evidence. International Journal of Bank Marketing, 13(2), 30-43. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/02652329510078677 Authors Sabina Taškar Beloglavec is a senior lecturer at the Faculty of Economics and Business of the University of Maribor. She completed her graduate and postgraduate studies at the University of Maribor, Faculty of Business and Economics. She is active in other fields of interest, outside her major occupation, including economic subject curriculum development and supervision for secondary schools and high school at The National Education Institute of the Republic of Slovenia. She has published several national and international articles and other publications (see IZUM - SICRIS, 20429). Urban Šebjan is currently a Ph.D. student in the Department of Quantitative Economic Analysis and Organization and Informatics at the University of Maribor-Faculty of Economics and Business. He has long worked with Triglav Insurance Company. His research focuses primarily on quantitative methods, statistical analysis software, analytical CRM, and modern information technology. He is employed by the Faculty of Economics and Business as an assistant in the field of quantitative economic analysis. Ali je zaupanje v banke v Sloveniji na preizkušnji? Izvleček Vprašanje stabilnosti bančnega sistema in zaupanje v banke sta, zlasti od leta 2008 naprej, v središču iskanja trajnih rešitev za težave bančnega sistema, ki temelji na zaupanju, trenutno stanje pa vpliva na vedenje uporabnikov bančnih storitev. V prispevku proučujemo zaupanje uporabnikov v banke v času finančne krize z izbranimi demografskimi spremenljivkami in s tem povezano možnost dviga prihrankov z bančnih računov. Rezultati raziskave so za banke koristni pri učinkovitem upravljanju prihrankov uporabnikov in razumevanju vedenja uporabnikov v času finančne krize. Med drugim smo namreč ugotovili, da obstaja negativna povezava med zaupanjem uporabnikov v banke in dvigom prihrankov uporabnikov bančnih storitev v času finančne krize, rezultati pa so odvisni od spola in ravni izobrazbe. Ključne besede: zaupanje, finančna institucija, banka, Slovenija, logistična regresija NAVODILA AVTORJEM INSTRUCTIONS FOR AUTHORS Revija Naše gospodarstvo / Our Economy objavlja znanstvene članke iz vseh področij ekonomije in poslovnih ved. Avtorje vabimo, da v uredništvo revije pošljejo originalne prispevke, ki še niso bili objavljeni oziroma poslani v objavo drugi reviji. Avtorji podeljujejo lastniku revije ekskluzivno pravico za komercialno uporabo članka, ki stopi v veljavo na osnovi sprejetja članka v objavo. Avtorji v celoti odgovarjajo za vsebino prispevka. Objavljamo samo članke, ki dobijo pozitivno oceno naših recenzentov. Prispevki naj bodo napisani v angleškem jeziku. Na posebni strani navedite ime avtorja, njegov polni habilitacijski in znanstveni naziv ter ustanovo, kjer je zaposlen. Prva stran naj vsebuje naslov, izvleček (maksimalno 650 znakov) in ključne besede, vse troje v slovenskem in angleškem jeziku. Dodajte tudi trimestno kodo JEL klasifikacije, ki jo najdete na https:// www.aeaweb.org/econlit/jelCodes.php?view=jel. Za besedilo članka uporabljajte praviloma pisave Times, Times New Roman CE, SL Dutch in podobne v velikosti od 10 do 12 pik (points). V tabelah in slikah obvezno uporabljajte pisavo brez serifov (Helvetico, Arial, Arial CE, SL Swiss ali podobno). Za poudarke v besedilu uporabljajte poševni tisk, ne krepkega ali podčrtanega tiska. Morebitne tabele in slike naj bodo oštevilčene ter naslovljene nad, opombe in viri pa pod tabelo oziroma sliko. V tabelah uporabljajte enojne okvirje, debeline pol pike (1/2 point). Sprotne opombe naj bodo oštevilčene in navedene pod tekstom pripadajoče strani. Oštevilčite tudi morebitne enačbe. Vire v tekstu in v seznamu virov je potrebno urediti skladno z APA standardom - navodila na http://www.apastyle.org/learn/ tutorials/basics-tutorial.aspx. Nekaj osnovnih napotkov: Navedbe virov v tekstu Primer 1a: Another graphic way of determining the stationari-ty of time series is correlogram of autocorrelation function (Gujarati, 1995). Primer 1b: Another graphic way of determining the stationari-ty of time series is correlogram of autocorrelation function (Gujarati, 1995, p. 36). Primer 2a: Engle and Granger (1987) present critical values also for other cointegration tests. Primer 2b: Engle and Granger (1987, p. 89) present critical values also for other cointegration tests. Navedbe virov v seznamu virov Primer 1 - Knjiga: Gujarati, D. N. (1995). Basic Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill. Primer 2 - Članek v reviji: Engle, R. F., & Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing. Econometrica, 55(2), 251-276. Primer 3 - Poglavje v knjigi, prispevek v zborniku: MacKinnon, J. (1991). Critical Values for Cointegration Tests. In R. F. Engle & C.W. J. Granger, (Eds.), Long-Run Economic Relationships: Readings in Cointegration (pp. 191-215). Oxford: University Press. Primer 4 - Elektronski vir: Esteves, J., Pastor, J. A., & Casanovas, J. (2002). Using the Partial Least Square (PLS): Method to Establish Critical Success Factors Interdependence in ERP Implementation Projects. Retrieved from http://erp. ittoolbox.com/doc.asp?i=2321 Prispevek naj ne bo daljši od avtorske pole (30.000 znakov). Stran naj bo velikosti A4, s tricentimetrskimi robovi in oštevilčenimi stranmi. Izpis naj bo enokolonski z 1,5 razmika med vrsticami. Elektronsko verzijo prispevka pošljite v MS Word obliki na e-naslov our.economy@um.si ali nase.gospodarstvo@um.si. S prispevkom pošljite za avtorja in vse soavtorje še celotni naslov, elektronski naslov in telefonsko številko, preko katere je dosegljiv uredništvu. Dodajte tudi kratek CV (obsega od 500 do 550 znakov, upoštevajoč presledke). The journal Naše gospodarstvo / Our Economy publishes original scientific articles covering all areas of economics and business. Authors are invited to send original unpublished articles which have not been submitted for publication elsewhere. Authors are completely responsible for the contents of their articles. Only articles receiving a favorable review are published. The authors grant the Journal Owner the exclusive license for commercial use of the article throughout the world, in any form, in any language, for the full term of copyright, effective upon acceptance for publication. Please write your text in English (American or British usage is accepted, but not a mixture of these). The cover page should include the author's name, academic title or profession, and affiliation. The first page must contain the title, an abstract of no more than 650 characters, and key words, all in English. Add also three-character codes of JEL classification (https://www. aeaweb.org/econlit/jelCodes.php?view=jel). Manuscripts should be prepared on a word processor in a font such as Times, Times New Roman CE, or SL Dutch in size 10 to 12 points. Tables and figures are to be presented in fonts without serifs (Helvetica, Arial, Arial CE, SL Swiss or similar). Emphasized parts of the text should be in italics, not bold or underlined. Figures and tables should be numbered with a title above and notes and sources below. Figures should be in ¥i point single-line frames. Footnotes should be numbered consecutively and placed at the bottom of the relevant page. Equations should also be numbered. References in the text and in the list of references should be arranged according to APA style - see http://www.apastyle.org/learn/ tutorials/basics-tutorial.aspx. Some elementary directions: References in the text Example 1a: Another graphic way of determining the station-arity of time series is correlogram of autocorrelation function (Gujarati, 1995). Example 1b: Another graphic way of determining the station-arity of time series is correlogram of autocorrelation function (Gujarati, 1995, p. 36). Example 2a: Engle and Granger (1987) present critical values also for other cointegration tests. Example 2b: Engle and Granger (1987, p. 89) present critical values also for other cointegration tests. References in the list of references Example 1 - Book: Gujarati, D. N. (1995). Basic Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill. Example 2 - Journal article: Engle, R. F., & Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing. Econometrica, 55(2), 251-276. Example 3 - Book chapter or article from conference proceedings: MacKinnon, J. (1991). Critical Values for Cointegration Tests. In R. F. Engle & C.W. J. Granger, (Eds.), Long-Run Economic Relationships: Readings in Cointegration (pp. 191-215). Oxford: University Press. Example 4 - Web source: Esteves, J., Pastor, J. A., & Casanovas, J. (2002). Using the Partial Least Square (PLS): Method to Establish Critical Success Factors Interdependence in ERP Implementation Projects. Retrieved from http://erp.ittoolbox.com/ doc.asp?i=2321 The size of the article should not exceed 30,000 characters and should be prepared on A4 paper with 3 cm margins and numbered pages. The text should be in single column layout, with 1.5 line spacing. Send the electronic version of article in MS Word to the following address: our.economy@um.si or nase.gospodarstvo@um.si. For the author and co-authors please add their postal address, e-mail address, telephone number as well as their CV (which range from 500 to 550 characters including spaces) in one paragraph. NG LETNIK VOLUME 61