247 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 | 247-277 ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION OF AN ADDITIONAL CARBON TAX ON THE SLOVENIAN ECONOMY CONSIDERING DIFFERENT FORMS OF RECYCLING 1 ALEKSANDAR KEŠELJEVIĆ 2 Received: 29 April 2013 MATJAŽ KOMAN 3 Accepted: 14 November 2014 ABSTRACT: This paper outlines some of the environmental and economic implications of an additional CO2 tax of EUR 15/tCO2 in Slovenia in the period 2012-2030 in order to deter- mine whether it yield a double dividend. Authors analyze (using E3ME model) different forms of revenue recycling by reducing the social security contributions of either the employ- ers or the employees or by reducing the public deficit, in order to identify the optimal fiscal instrument for improving the environmental and economic welfare (double dividend). In this policy orientated paper authors argue that a reduction of employee social security contribu- tions has more favourable effect than a reduction in employers' social security contributions. Keywords: green tax, environmental tax reform, double dividend, carbon tax, recycling, E3ME model JEL Classification: E17, H23, Q50 1. INTRODUCTION – GREEN TAXES AND ENVIRONMENTAL TAX REFORM (ETR) The idea of a green tax dates back to Arthur C. Pigou (1920); hence, green tax is also referred to as a Pigouvian tax. It is based upon a fundamental principle that the polluters should pay a tax in the amount equal to the damages resulting from their impact on the environment (i.e. negative externalities). The costs are namely not incurred only by the company whose emissions pollute the environment; rather, the costs are sustained by the entire society. It is then the task of the government to impose the green tax to internalize the pollution costs as much as possible. In such case, the polluting industrial activity is reduced to a socially desirable level (Turner, 1994). Introduction of the green tax represents also an important development in the public finance reform since it involves also a reconsideration of the present tax system, aimed 1 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: Kešeljević's and Koman's research in this paper was supported by grant No V5- 1004 of the Slovenian Research Agency (ARRS) and the Institute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Development (UMAR). The authors would like to thank Katarina Ivas from Insitute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Develop- ment and people from Cambridge Econometrics, specially Eva Alexandri, for helpful comments and suggestions. 2 University of Ljubljana, Faculty of Economics, Ljubljana, Slovenia, e-mail: saso.keseljevic@ef.uni-lj.si 3 University of Ljubljana, Faculty of Economics, Ljubljana, Slovenia, e-mail: matjaz.koman@ef.uni-lj.si ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 248 predominantly at taxing labour and capital. The environmental tax reform (ETR) argues in favour of green taxes in a revenue-neutral fashion to reduce other distortionary levies. Instead of taxing “good things” like labour, income and capital, the government should start taxing “bad things” like pollution, use of natural resources etc. (Bousqet, 2000; Pat- uelli et al., 2005). The main goal of an environmental tax reform is therefore an improve- ment in both environmental (first dividend) and economical aspects (second dividend). Environmental dividend involves reduction in emissions and economic dividend stems from lower costs, improved competitiveness, and higher employment. Therefore, the term “double dividend” is increasingly used to describe the environmental tax reform (Glomm et al., 2008; Ekins, 2009). Experience from European countries has shown, that effects of a comprehensive ETR have been positive in most cases (Sweden, Denmark, Netherlands, UK, Finland, Norway, Ger- many). Therefore, the environmental tax reforms (ETR) have become a relevant instru- ment in the economic policies of the developed world in recent years. Our primary goal is to determine the effect of an additional carbon tax (EUR 15 per ton of CO2 i.e. EUR 55 per ton of carbon) in the period 2012–2030 on the Slovenian economy, in order to determine whether an additional carbon tax would indeed yield a double divi- dend. We shall examine the possibilities of different recycling options either through re- duction of budget deficit or reduction of employer/employee social security contributions, in the form of different scenarios (using E3ME model) in order to identify the optimal fiscal instrument for improving the environmental (first dividend) and economic welfare (second dividend). The article is structured as follows. In section two the concept of double dividend is intro- duced. In section three we present the E3ME model and the impact of green taxes within the model. Results regarding the environmental and economic implications of an envi- ronmental tax reform are presented in section four. Finally, the last section deals with the conclusions and policy implications derived from the contents of the paper. 2. A DOUBLE DIVIDEND The two central dilemmas regarding the green tax have to do with regressiveness and loss of competitiveness. Many authors have argued that incidence of green taxes falls largely on the low-income class (Roed, 2006; West, Williams, 2004; Labandeira, Labeaga, 1999; Tiezzi, 2001; Clinch et al., 2006). Negative effect on cost competitiveness of the economy will be greater when (1) elasticity of demand for a certain good is relatively high; (2) there is strong competition in the industry; (3) a particular sector is highly energy-intensive; (4) ecotax is introduced in a small number of countries; and (5) there is no option to substitute the polluting activity with an environmentally friendlier technology (Kosonen, Nicodème, 2009; Clinch et al., 2006; Patuelli et al., 2005; Baron, 1997; Envoldsen et al., 2009). Thus, if the government introduces ETR without recycling the tax revenue within the system, an economic downturn would likely occur. A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 249 Recycling in this case refers to targeted use of green tax revenue, especially for reducing the taxation of labour and social security contributions. Besides a reduction of social security contributions or personal income taxes, other forms of financial recycling are also possible by transfers to households/industries for greater energy efficiency 4 or interventions in cor- porate income taxes and value added tax. In case of total recycling, the total tax burden re- mains unchanged (fiscal neutrality) (Speck, Jilkova, 2009; Ludewig et al., 2010; OECD, 2007; Hoerner, Bosquet, 2001; Clinch et al., 2006; Patuelli et al., 2005; Hansen, Holger, 2000). We expect an environmental tax reform to lead to an improvement from environmen- tal aspects, e.g. owing to lower carbon dioxide emissions, as well as to improve the cost competitiveness of the economy as a result of lower labour costs and higher technological efficiency of businesses. Hence, economic growth and employment will actually increase (Benoit, 2000; Hoerner et al., 2001; Patuelli et al., 2005; Tuladhar, Wilcoxen, 1999). Not surprisingly, the European countries with the highest tax on labour were the first to im- plement the environmental tax reform and look for double dividend (Finland, Sweden, Denmark, Netherlands, Germany, and Norway). The first (environmental) dividend of the double dividend hypothesis is widely accepted. Johansson (2000) argues that in Sweden the CO2 emissions were 15% lower than they would have been in the absence of the green taxes. Berkhout and Linderhof (2001) point out that in the Netherlands, the price of electricity and fuel for domestic use rose dramati- cally as a result of the green tax and ex-post studies show that consumers now use 15% less electricity and 5–10% less fuel. Baron (1997) pointed out that in Denmark recycling of tax revenues through investment in energy efficiency has led to about 4.7% reduction in CO2 emissions. Labandeira et al. (2004) show that in Spain a tax on CO2 emissions has resulted in environmental improvement. Ludewig et al. (2010) demonstrate that use of all motor fuels in Germany was decreasing in the period from 1995 to 2006 by an average rate of 0.3 percent per year. At the same time, use of public transport was rising. Based on an analysis of 139 simulation models, Bosquet (2000) found that a considerable drop in carbon dioxide emissions is among the expected effects of a green tax reform in the short to medium run. The second (economic) dividend depends mainly on the structure of the economy (e.g. labour market, pre-existing tax structure), time lag and explicit model assumptions. Since the present tax system creates significant disincentives to work and hire, virtually any environmental policy can compound these existing distortions (Carraro et al., 1996; Mor- genstern, 1995; Tuladhar, Wilcoxen, 1999; Schöb, 2003). Ludewig et al. (2010) find that 250,000 new jobs were created in Germany in this way. Experience from Denmark (Hans- en, Holger, 2000) and Spain (Manresa, Ferran 2005) is similar. However, many authors argue that the “double dividend” theory oversimplifies a number of points and that certain conditions have to be fulfilled for a double dividend. 4 Alternative recycling method are: (1) improvements in the energy efficiency of the building stock, (2) grants for improving energy efficiency in buildings, (3) recycling into local environmental projects to foster communi- ty acceptance of ETR, (4) recycling to public transport, (5) subsidising renewable energy and combined heat and power production, (6) subsidising ‘cleaner’ technology in industry, (7) subsidising R&D (Clinch et al., 2006). ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 250 Firstly, ETR is expected to improve the quality of the environment and to reduce the dis- tortions of existing taxes. This view has been questioned in several papers (Goulder, 1995; Benoit, 2000; De Mooij, 1999; Li, Ren, 2012). The basic point is that the double divi- dend hypothesis ignores the interaction between environmental taxes and pre-existing tax structure. If the initial tax system is suboptimal then ETR can generate a significant double dividend. Similarly Fraser and Waschik (2013) using a CGE model to empirically exam- ine the double dividend hypothesis provide support for the existence of a strong double dividend when revenue is recycled through reductions especially in consumption taxes. Secondly, the outcome depends very much on labour market conditions in the country (Clinch et al., 2006; Carraro et al., 1996; Schöb, 2003; Koskela and Schob, 1999; Holmlund and Kolm, 2000; Albrecht, 2006; Ciaschini et al., 2012). If there are labour rigidities (as in some countries of Europe), then there will be an employment dividend resulting from the recycled carbon tax revenue. But in the long run, such rigidities become less relevant. Thirdly, green taxes represent, as a rule, a relatively small share of overall tax revenue of any given country 5 . Hence, a dramatic increase would be required to offset the lower per- sonal income tax revenue. Thus, if green taxes are set high enough to achieve meaningful reductions in emissions, they may cause significant distortions in the tax system. Policy makers will then be forced to trade off cleaner environment against other policy targets (Coxhead, 2000). Fourthly, Carraro et al (1996) find that the unions’ negotiating strength affects the possi- bility of gains in employment. In the short run the employment may increase due to lower taxes; however, in the long run, net wages completely absorb the tax change, thus bringing employment back to its baseline value. Many authors argue that the effects of a green tax reform are doubtful in the long run. Nevertheless, while the second dividend may be in doubt, the first dividend remains a powerful argument for the introduction of ETR. Obviously, a strong double dividend oc- curs under rather “constrained” circumstances. We do not go more into the details since the rise and fall of the double dividend hypothesis and conditions for it has been discussed at length elsewhere (Bovenberg and Goulder 1997; Parry and Oates, 1998; Goulder, 1995; Bosquet, 2000; Fraser and Waschik, 2013). All authors agree that validity of the double- dividend hypothesis cannot be settled as a general matter. In other words, each reform must be evaluated on its own merits by keeping in mind the characteristics of respective countries and the explicit model assumptions. 5 In most EU countries, revenue from green taxes is between 2% and 3% of GDP. There are only four EU coun- tries where such share in lower than 2% (1.9% in Slovakia, 1.9% in Lithuania, 1.6% in Spain, 1.8% in France), and only three countries where this share exceeds 3.5% of GDP (4% in Denmark, 4% in the Netherlands, 3.6% in Slovenia). Green taxes represent the largest share of total tax revenue in Bulgaria (10.7%), the Netherlands (10.3%), and Slovenia (9.6%). The lowest contribution of green taxes to overall tax revenue was observed in France (4.2%), Belgium (4.7%), and Spain (5.2%). Slovenia is considerably above the EU27 average (6.2%) with its 9.6-percent share of green tax revenue in overall tax revenue (European Commission, 2012). A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 251 3. THE MODEL There are two different methodological approaches to modelling the relation between the environment and the rest of the economy. The first approach is based on highly precise modelling of a certain sector; as a rule, however, such models do not yield the best expla- nations as to the interaction between the sector at hand and the economy as a whole. The other approach is based on structural macroeconomic models. A key advantage of these models, each of them is based on certain underlying assumptions, is that they allow a fairly accurate prediction of macroeconomic results in case of different scenarios. These models provide a better understanding of the economic consequences of environmental measures as they allow studying the economic processes that lead to final results. The downside of these models is that each sector is modelled at the aggregated level 6 . Our analysis is based on the latter approach. We employed the E3ME 7 model, widely used among European researchers in recent years. This is a dynamic simulation econometric model intended for analysis of the effects of E3 policies (economy, energy, environment), es- pecially those pertaining to environmental taxes and regulation. The model allows examin- ing the short-term (annual) and medium-term economic effects, as well as long-term effects of E3 policies for a period of 20 years. Hence, E3ME combines the features of short-term and medium-term sector models estimated using econometric methods with the features of computational general equilibrium models. The E3ME model includes 42 product/industry sectors (OECD classification), with energy sector further disaggregated to include energy- environment interaction and 16 service sectors. It is intended for analysis of macroeconomic effects (with emphasis on environmental components) of environmental economic policies, especially from the aspect of environmental taxation and regulation, for 33 European coun- tries (EU27, Norway, Switzerland, Iceland, Croatia, Turkey, and Macedonia) as a whole. It also allows analysis of environmental effects in each country 8 . The structure of E3ME is based on the System of National Accounts (ESA 95), with ad- ditional links to demand for energy and environmental emissions. The model includes a total of 33 sets of econometrically estimated equations which also include components of the GDP (consumption, investment, international trade), prices, demand for energy, and demand for raw materials. Each set of equations is broken down by countries and by sectors. E3ME also allows analyzing the effects of particular scenarios as measured by numerous economic, energy, and environmental indicators. The model is based on the data for the period from 1970 to 2010 and annual projections until the year 2050. The main sources of data include Eurostat, AMECO DC ECFIN database, and IEA; this data set is further complemented by OECD STAN and other databases. Any gaps in the data are estimated using adjusted software algorithms. For a detailed description of the E3ME model, see E3ME Manual (2012). 6 For a detailed description of methodological approaches in modelling the relations between the environ- ment and the economy, see Ščasný et al. (2009). 7 The model was developed and is maintained by the company Cambridge Econometrics. 8 See E3ME Manual (2012) for more detailed description. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 252 3.1. EFFECTS OF ECOLOGICAL TAXATION (GREEN TAX) IN THE E3ME MODEL One of the purposes of the E3ME model is to provide consistent and coherent analysis of fiscal policy and its relation to greenhouse gas emissions. The E3ME model allows exam- ining how carbon and energy taxes affect the reduction of environmental emissions, as well as how other taxation and economic policies affect reduction of emissions. The effect of a taxing carbon dioxide emissions (and energy consumption) in the E3ME model on prices and wages is based on two key assumptions. The first assumption is that the effect of tax is transmitted through the price of fuel and any use of subsequent tax revenue to reduce other taxes. Other effects are not modelled. The second assumption is that import of fuels and domestic production are taxed in proportion to the CO2 emission rate and energy value of the fuel, while fuel exports are not taxed. It is assumed that this tax is paid by the fuel producers and importers. This tax is then levied on the final users through higher fuel prices. Another assumption is that the industry will transmit these additional fuel costs on its buyers in the form of higher prices of commodities (goods and services). An increase in the final price is therefore a result of direct and indirect effect of tax on a particular good or service. If tax revenue is used to reduce the rates of taxes levied on the employers, this will result in a decrease of labour costs and, in turn, a drop in production costs. These changes, too, will then be transmitted forward within the E3ME model (E3ME Manual, 2012). Net effect of tax on prices of products and imports will be transmitted to consumer prices, resulting in a change in the consumption of goods and services. Such change will depend on individual ecotax and the price elasticity of the affected commodities. Higher prices of goods and services will lead to demands for higher wages. Econometric studies have confirmed that in the long run, entire tax is levied on the consumers. This fact is integrated into the E3ME model as a part of its long-term solution. In the E3ME model, ecotaxes indirectly influence (through direct effect on prices and wages) the macroeconomic parameters such as fuel consumption, production, employ- ment in particular sectors etc.). Namely, a change in the price of fuels resulting from eco- tax will, depending on the elasticity of substitution, lead to a change in fuel consumption. Increase of fuel prices due to higher taxes will cause changes in consumer prices, which will be reflected in substitution in consumer expenditure, change of export activity, and change in the relation between domestic production and imports. These changes will in turn affect, via feedback loop, the use of various types of fuel. A reduction in labour costs resulting from “recycling” of tax revenue will initially have a direct positive effect on em- ployment, followed by an indirect effect through relative price competitiveness thereon as more commodities (goods and services) are produced in labour intensive industries. 4. RESULTS OF THE MODEL Below we present the results of the introduction of the additional carbon tax. We firstly assume that all revenue generated from ecotax is allocated for reduction of the budget A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 253 deficit or increase of the budget surplus. In subsequent analyses, ecotaxes will be recycled in various ways, e.g. they will be used to reduce the taxes levied on labour costs. The analysis will be based in section 4.2. on a comparison to a base projection (baseline scenario), and in section 4.3. on a comparison to a budget recycling projection. Results will be presented in the form of a deviation from the base projection and the budget recy- cling projection. Therefore, we continue by presenting the assumption underlying the base projection, and the way in which this projection was generated. 4.1. DESCRIPTION OF THE BASE PROJECTION (BASELINE SCENARIO) AND UNDERLYING ASSUMPTIONS AND THE ESTIMATION METODOLOGY TOGETHER WITH PARAMETER RESULTS It is important that the baseline projection (baseline scenario) in the framework of the E3ME model is consistent with the forecasts used in other analyses. The underlying as- sumption of the baseline projection was that the E3ME projection was consistent with the slightly modified projection of the European commission (modified projection PRIMES BASELINE 2009). PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts are also presented in Table A1 in the Appendix. Following is a description of the key stages in modelling of the base projection. Inputs for the base projection include historical data (data on economic indicators, energy, and the environment, obtained from different sources (Eurostat, IEA etc.), estimates of param- eters for endogenous variables, and fundamental assumptions. Historical data on economic indicators for Slovenia (employment, output, consumption, exports etc.) is used up to and including 2010. The indicators were calculated from the data published by Eurostat in February 2012. Historical data on energy components (en- ergy consumption by types of fuel etc.) and environmental components is derived from the World Energy Outlook for the period up to 2009. Endogenous variables are determined using the functions estimated based on historical data. There are around 33 variables for which stochastic functions are estimated. However these variables may well be disaggregated in two dimensions (e.g. there are 19 fuel users and 33 countries) so we will not provide the specification of each variable. Below we first describe the general procedure how these stochastic functions are estimated and then show one example of such function and its parameters for Slovenia. The functional form of the equations and the parameters are based on the cointegration and error-correction methodology (Engle and Granger, 1987, and Hendry et al., 1984). The process involves two stages. The first-stage is a levels relationship, where an attempt is made to identify the existence of a cointegrating relationship between the chosen vari- ables, selected on the basis of economic theory and a priori reasoning. For example the aggregate energy demand (FRO) is specified as follows: ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 254 FR0 i,j,t = a i,j,0 + a i,j,1 FRY i,j,t + a i,j,2 PREN i,j,t + a i,j,3 FRTD i,j,t + a i,j,4 ZRDM t + a i,j,5ZRDTt + + a i,j,6 FRK i,j,t + u i,j,t where FRY is economic output of energy users i in region j, PREN is average fuel price (across all fuels) deflated by unit cost in region j, FRTD is R&D expenditure by energy user i in region j, ZRDM is EU investment of R&D in machinery, ZRDT is EU investment of R&D in transport, and FRK is investment by energy user i in region j If a cointegrating relationship exists, then the second stage regression, known as the error- correction representation, is implemented. It involves a dynamic, first-difference, regres- sion of all the variables from the first stage, along with lags of the dependent variable, lagged differences of the exogenous variables, and the error-correction term (the lagged residual from the first stage regression). Due to limitations of data size, however, only one lag of each variable is included in the second-stage. For example in case of aggregate energy demand the error correction equation is specified as: ∆FR0 i,j,t = b i,j,0 + b i,j,1∆ FRY i,j,t + b i,j,2∆ PREN j,t + b i,j,3 DFRTD i,j,t + b i,j,4 ∆ZRDM t + b i,j,5 ∆ZRDT t + b i,j,6 ∆FRK i,j,t + b i,j,7 ∆FR0 i,j,t-1 + g i,j, ECM i,j,t-1 , where ∆ is difference and ECM is error correction. Stationarity tests on the residual from the levels equation are performed to check whether a cointegrating set is obtained. Due to the size of the model, the equations are estimated individually rather than through a cointegrating V AR. For both regressions, the estimation technique used is instrumental variables, principally because of the simultaneous nature of many of the relationships (for example wage, employment and price determination). E3ME’s parameter estimate is carried out using a customised set of software routines based in the Ox programming language (Doornik, 2007). The main advantage of using this approach is that parameters for all sectors and countries may be estimated using an automated approach. The estimation produces a full set of standard econometric diagnostics, including stand- ard errors and tests for endogeneity. However all the estimation procedures and test are carried out by Cambridge Econometrics, the developer of the software 9 . In Table A2 in appendix we provide a summary of the model equations, giving an over- view of which variables are used, units of measurement and functional form. A full list of the variables included in E3ME model is available on request. In Appendix 1 we also pre- sent in more detail the agregate demand for energy function and the estimated parameters for Slovenia. The other functions and parameters for Slovenia are available upon request. 9 A list of equation results can be made available on request. For each equation, the following information will be given: summary of results, full list of parameter results, full list of standard deviations. A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 255 The gaps in any of the E3ME time series was filled by software that was developed by the Cambridge Econometrics. This software uses growth rates and shares between sectors and variables to estimate missing data points, both in cases of interpolation and extrapolation. More precisely, “ The most straightforward case is when the growth rates of a variable are known and so the level can be estimated from these growth rates, as long as the initial level is known. Sharing is used when the time-series data of an aggregation of sectors are available but the individual time series is not. In this case, the sectoral time series can be calculated by sharing the total, using either actual or estimated shares. In the case of extrapolation, it is often the case that aggregate data for a number of sectors are available, although the sectoral disaggregation at the E3ME level is not; for example, government expenditure is a good proxy for the total growth in education, health and defence. A special procedure has been put in place to estimate the growth in more disaggregated sectors so that the sum of these matches the known total, while the individual sectoral growth follows the characteristics of each sector. Interpolation is used when no external source is available, to estimate the path interval, at the beginning and end of which data are available” . (E3ME, 2014, page 34) Basic assumptions are derived from various sources. The sources are presented in Table A3 in the Appendix. For Slovenia, the values of these assumptions for the period 2010– 2013 are presented in Table A4 in the Appendix. In the same table values of assumptions for particular commodities (e.g. energy prices, fuel prices etc.) are also presented. The baseline scenario is therefore based on all government measures implemented until mid 2010. For example, the CO2 price is determined on the measures introduced by the Slove- nian government by mid 2010. The process of ensuring compliance of the base projection in the E3ME model involves three stages. This is in fact a calibration process. The first stage in reconciling the E3ME projections with the published and slightly modified forecast PRIMES BASELINE 2009 (EU Energy trends to 2030, Baseline scenario 2009, European Commission, 2010). It includes ensuring consistency and transformation of the data into a suitable form. This means that different model dimensions have to be brought into line (geographic coverage, temporal aspect, sector coverage etc.). Transformed data are then saved in a separate file. In the next stage, the model is resolved in such way that model results match the slightly modified PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts saved in a separate file. This is the calibrated forecasting process. In this forecast, the model solves its equations and compares the dif- ferences in results with the data saved in the database. Model results are substituted with values from the forecast database. Differences between results and forecasts are saved in a separate database called the “residual” database. In the last stage, the model is solved again using the “residual” database as well. This is the so-called endogenous baseline pro- jection. According the theory, the final result should be the same as in the case of calibrat- ed forecast. In practice, the match is not 100-percent (see, E3ME manual, pages 40–41). In the E3ME model framework, the calibration process with modified PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts is carried out based on the trends (growth rates) rather than based on levels. This is because historical data in the E3ME model are newer that the data from the modified PRIMES BASELINE 2009. Calibrations for PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts are made for ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 256 the key economic variables and demand for energy (variables FRO, FRO1, FRO2 ... FRO12) and data on emissions (variables GHG, FCO2 etc.).   However, since PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts are based on the year 2010 and they do not include the most recent changes in the economic environment (the economic crisis), short-term calibration for macroeco- nomic variables is conducted based on AMECO short-term forecasts. Therefore, the base- line scenario is made based on the modified PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts. The key advantage of the endogenous baseline projection is that it allows us to analyse different scenarios in order to find out how the results change relative to the baseline scenario. There are two baseline endogenous projections: SI endogenous baseline projec- tion and EU endogenous baseline projection. For the SI endogenous baseline projection, calibration is only carried out for Slovenia while other European regions are treated as exogenous. This projection is used in analysis of scenarios that only affect Slovenia (e.g. a change in domestic tax rate). EU endogenous baseline projection involves simultaneously solving the E3ME model for the entire Europe. This projection is used for scenarios that will affect the entire Europe (e.g. a change in oil prices). If this solution is used, results for Slovenia will also include secondary effects from other European regions, brought about through international trade. Since the introduction of the additional carbon tax in Slovenia is only affecting the Slo- venian economy, SI endogenous projection will be used. The remaining part of Europe is treated as exogenous 10 . It is important to stress, that all scenarios that will be presented 11 are based on (1) his- torical data up to and including the year 2009 (energy and environmental components) or the year 2010 (economic components); (2) on government measures implemented by mid 2010; (3) and on long-term and short-term trends energy and environmental com- ponents, that are based on the European Commission projections from 2009 (PRIMES BASELINE 2009). Long-term trends for macroeconomic components are also based on European Commission projections from 2009 (PRIMES BASELINE 2009) while short- term macroeconomic components are based on the AMECO projections. This means that the effects of the economic crisis are only partially included and, as a result, the below results should be used with caution. 4.2. ANALYSIS OF INTRODUCTION OF AN ADDITIONAL CARBON TAX ON THE SLOVENIAN ECONOMY It is assumed within the E3ME model that payment of carbon tax (tax on carbon dioxide) is levied on the users of fuels based on their emissions; however, only sectors outside ETS are taxed in order to avoid double taxation. The cost, or burden, of the tax is then shifted to the consumers through higher fuel prices. 10 We have also introduced the additional carbon tax in Slovenia by using EU endogenous baseline projec- tion. The results were very similar. 11 Values of particular variables for all scenarios to be used herein are presented in Table A5 in the appendix. A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 257 In consequence, this means that we can expect the prices to rise while demand for fuel drops. It is assumed that higher prices will lead to a drop in real income. We can expect household consumption expenditure to decrease, which will in turn decrease demand and cause a drop in gross domestic product. As we assumed this change would not affect the European economy, we expect this will result in a drop of export competitiveness of the Slovenian economy due to higher prices, which will lead to a further decrease in GDP . According to economic theory, the amount of carbon tax should be equal to the social cost incurred as a result of carbon pollution. Y ohe et al. (2007) reviewed the estimates and found that costs estimates are highly unpredictable as they range from USD 1 per ton of carbon (tC) up to USD 1,500 per ton of carbon (tC). Average estimate of social cost of pollution with carbon dioxide for 2005 was USD 43/tC, with a standard deviation of USD 83/tC. The authors found that these costs rise at a rate of 2 to 4 percent per year. Assum- ing 4-percent annual growth since 2005, carbon pollution cost in 2012 would amount to an average of USD 55/tC or EUR 42/tC (i.e. EUR 11.5/tCO2. We set the amount of extra carbon tax to EUR 15/tCO2 (i.e. EUR 55/tC) 12 . In the article we compare two scenarios: baseline scenario in which no extra carbon tax is introduced and the projection of an introduction of an additional annual carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15 per ton of CO2 (EUR 15 per ton of carbon) for sectors beyond ETS, where all ecotax is recycled into the government budget. Comparison between the two projections is made for some key economic (household consumption expenditure, exports, gross domestic product, total manufacturing output, employment), energy (aver- age fuel prices, demand for energy), and environmental variables (greenhouse emissions) which are presented in detail below. Average fuel prices including tax (PJRT 13 ) change the most in the first year following the in- troduction of the carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) (2012) when they rise by 3.67% relative to the baseline scenario in which no extra carbon tax is introduced. After the initial price hike, the price reaches a steady state at a higher figure which is main- tained throughout the examined period. The difference in the average fuel price between the baseline scenario and projection that assumes an additional carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (or EUR 55/tC) is approximately 3.5% throughout the period at hand (until 2030). As expected, the introduction of an extra carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) drives up the average prices of fuel, which in turn causes a decrease in demand for fuels for en- ergy production (FRO 14 ). This drop relative to the baseline scenario is relatively the largest in the initial period, after which the decrease in demand for energy is steadied or slowed down. In 2013, for example, demand for energy resulting from the introduction of the car- bon tax was projected to be lower by 0.83% compared to the baseline scenario; in 2020 by 12 Determination of the size of the ecotax has been aligned with the Institute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Development (UMAR). We have also used other numbers for ecotax, but we do not report them in the article. 13 PJRT = Average fuel price including tax (in EUR/toe). The model assumes 12 different fuel consumers. 14 FRO = Total demand for energy is in E3ME model measured in thousand tons toe. Model assumes 12 dif- ferent fuel consumers. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 258 1.64%; and in 2025 by 1.9%. Initial increase in prices and a considerable drop in demand relative to the baseline scenario are followed by a higher and steady level of fuel prices and accordingly lower demand for energy throughout the period of examination. Household consumption expenditure (RSC 15 ) is one of the most important macroeco- nomic aggregates, since it takes the largest share of GDP structure. Introduction of extra annual carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) would lead to the highest relative drop of household consumption expenditure in 2013 when the decrease amounts to 0.45% rela- tive to the baseline scenario with no introduction of carbon tax. In principle, higher av- erage prices of fuel lead to a decrease in real income which in turn decreases household consumption expenditure. This would result in a drop in aggregate demand and cause a decrease in gross domestic product. After 2013, the difference relative to the baseline scenario gradually decreases and by 2020, for example, consumption is only 0.27% lower compared to the baseline scenario. As expected, the difference between the two scenarios is the largest at the beginning of the period; after 2013, it is gradually decreasing. Moreo- ver, the data shows a relatively low effect of the introduction of the carbon tax on the change in consumption. The reasons can be found in the time lag as the consumers require some time to adjust their behaviour and consumption pattern. If the extra annual carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) is introduced, exports (RSX 16 ) will decrease relative to the baseline scenario in which no carbon tax is introduced in the short run (until 2017), and increase after 2018. Such development is ex- pected as we assumed the change would not affect the European economy. Higher prices expectedly hinder the export competitiveness of the Slovenian economy; however, the ex- port sector’s agility and dynamic character in terms of development of new technological solutions and updates will allow it to neutralize relatively quickly such loss of competitive- ness. It should also be noted that changes in exports relative to the baseline scenario are very small (up to a maximum of 0.009%), which points to a relatively low impact of the carbon tax on Slovenian exports. Introduction of extra annual carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) would lead to the highest drop of Slovenia’s GDP (RGDP 17 ) in 2013 when the decrease would amount to 0.3% relative to the baseline scenario with no introduction of carbon tax. This is consistent with our expectations. It has been shown in our previous analysis that higher fuel prices lead to a decrease of real income. As a result, household consumption expenditure will decrease, which will in turn decrease demand and cause a drop in gross domestic product. As we assumed this change would not affect the European economy, higher prices would also result in a drop of export competitiveness of the Slovenian econ- omy, which would lead to a further decrease in GDP . Moreover, the data shows a relatively low effect of the introduction of the said tax on the change in GDP . After 2013, the differ- ence between the two scenarios gradually decreases and by 2020, for example, GDP is only 15 RSC = Household consumption expenditure is in E3ME model measured in EUR million. The model as- sumes 43 different types of expenditure. 16 RSX = Exports are measured in E3ME model in million euro. 17 RGDP = Gross domestic product is in E3ME model measured by the expenditure method in current mar- ket prices in millions of euro. A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 259 0.12% lower in case of introduction of the carbon tax compared to the baseline scenario. This conforms to our expectations and the theoretical findings as economic agents require some time to adjust to the new circumstances. Businesses need time to implement techno- logical improvements and updates, and consumers need time to adjust their consumption behaviour and patterns. We are also interested in the effect of an extra yearly carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) on manufacturing output (QR 18 ). The highest drop relative to the baseline sce- nario would be in 2015. In that year, the difference would amount to 0.32%. Here too, it is evident that introduction of carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2 (or EUR 55/ tC) has a relatively small effect on production. The difference between the two scenarios is, expectedly, the highest at the start of the period. After 2013, this difference is gradu- ally decreasing so that the deviation from the baseline scenario in 2015 is no more than 0.01%. Technological and organizational updates allowed the enterprises to adapt to the new conditions after a certain period of time. According to the projection, the latter effect prevails in the long run, after 2027. Employment (YRE 19 ) shows a similar dynamics as manufacturing output. Employment is gradually decreasing relative to the baseline scenario. The highest drop in comparison to the baseline scenario can be seen in 2016 when it amounts to 0.36%. There are hardly any differences between the two scenarios at the end of the period. The effect of an additional carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (or EUR 55/tC) on employment appears to be relatively low, similarly to the effect on GDP and manufacturing output. As expected, the introduction of an extra carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) grad- ually decreases greenhouse gas emissions (RGHG 20 ) in CO2 equivalents. This includes emissions of CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs and SF6. For example, the highest drop in emissions relative to the baseline scenario is seen in 2012 (by 0.6%) and 2013 (by an extra 0.5%) to –1.2%. The decrease in emissions in comparison to the baseline scenario is stead- ied at approximately 2% after 2020. 4.3. ANALYSIS OF DIFFERENT FORMS OF REVENUE RECYCLING IN CASE OF EXTRA CARBON TAX IN THE SLOVENIAN ECONOMY Introduction of an extra annual carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) on an annual basis for the period 2012–2030 would result in additional annual tax revenue ranging from a minimum amount of EUR 144.6 million in year 2012 to a maximum amount of EUR 160.1 million in year 2020. The additional tax revenue can be allocated to the econ- omy through different revenue recycling options. We compare the following five revenue recycling options (in each option we have introduced a yearly carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC), while other assumptions remain the same as in the baseline scenario): 18 QR = total manufacturing output (EUR million). The model is based on an analysis of 42 different sectors. 19 YRE = Employment (thousands). The model is based on an analysis of 42 different industries. 20 RGHG = Greenhouse gas emissions (in CO2 equivalent thousands of tons) ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 260 a) The first scenario analyses the effects of introduction of the extra carbon tax and revenue recycling through a decrease in the budget deficit and tax revenue. b) In the second scenario, we study the effects of revenue recycling through a decrease in social security contributions for the workers/employees, equivalent to the amount of green tax revenue (fiscal neutrality). Although the yearly decrease of workers’ social con- tributions varies by year, depending on the green tax collected, the average decrease in the period 2012-2030 was 0.6 percentage points i.e. the worker social contributions were on average equal to 18.0% in the observed period (2012-2030). c) In the third scenario we analyse the effects of revenue recycling through a corresponding decrease in social security contributions payable by the employers subject to the princi- ple of fiscal neutrality. Although the yearly decrease of employers’ social contributions varies by year, depending on the green tax collected, the average decrease in the period 2012-2030 was 0.6 percentage points i.e. the employers’ social contributions were on average equal to 13.0% in the observed period. d) In the fourth scenario we allocate the green tax revenue for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in workers’ social security contributions in 2017 and thereafter. Assuming fiscal neutrality, green tax revenue were first allocated to the budget (period 2012-2016) and for the period 2017-2030 we decreased the work- ers’ social security contributions on average to 18.1%. e) In the fifth scenario, revenue is recycled through a decrease in budget deficit in the first five years (2012–2016); then, social security contributions payable by the employers are decreased by the relevant amount. Applying the principle of fiscal neutrality, the latter were decreased on average to 13.1% (0.5 percentage points) in the period 2017–2030. A comparison between different types of recycling will be made especially for some key economic variables (household consumption expenditure, gross domestic product, manufacturing output, employment). Analysis of revenue recycling will be based on a comparison of the second, third, fourth, and fifth scenario, respectively, to the first one. We wish to determine the existence of the double dividend based on a decrease of some social security contributions, improvement in cost competitiveness and the resulting rise in GDP and employment. Effect on household consumption expenditure Figure 1 presents the effect on household consumption expenditure (RSC) in case of dif- ferent options of recycling of the revenue generated by the extra yearly carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2. In our analysis, four scenarios (2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th scenario) are compared to the projection in which all carbon tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). Figure 1 shows that the positive effect on household consumption expenditure in all four scenarios is stronger than in case of the projection in which all generated tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). This is expected as additional relief through lower social contributions may increase the general population’s purchasing power as net wages rise. Furthermore, it can be observed that revenue recycling through workers’ social contribu- tions has a higher effect on household consumption expenditure than recycling through A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 261 social security contributions payable by the employers in the entire period at hand (both rel- ative to the first scenario). The difference in household consumption expenditure between the two revenue recycling options is decreasing through the years. The reasons can be found in the fact that a decrease in employers’ social security contributions would translate to a lower extent into an increase in net wages and the resulting increase in consumption than it would be the case if social security contributions were decreased for the workers. The result is similar in the case where we allocate the green tax revenue for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in workers’ social se- curity contributions in 2017 and thereafter. In this case, too, decrease of social security contributions for the workers has a stronger positive effect on household consumption ex- penditure than a decrease of social security contributions for the employers (both in com- parison to the first scenario). Similar as before, the differences between the two scenarios through the years are gradually decreasing. Figure 1 also shows that the best scenarios from the aspect of revenue recycling are the ones that decrease social security contribu- tions for the workers (scenarios 2 and 4). These two scenarios are only different in the first five years; after that, their results tend to match. Similar match can be seen between the two scenarios in which the employer’s social security contributions are reduced. It should also be noted that the differences between all scenarios referred to are relatively small. Figure 1: Comparison between different forms of carbon tax revenue recycling from the aspect of effect on household consumption expenditure, RSC. Source: E3ME program and own calculations. Effect on gross domestic product Figure 2 shows the effect of introduction of a yearly carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/ tCO2 on GDP (RGDP) in different cases of tax revenue recycling. In our analysis, four scenarios (2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th scenario) are compared to the first scenario in which 1 0 0,1 0,2 0,3 0,4 0,5 0,6 20 11 20 13 20 15 20 17 20 19 20 21 20 23 20 25 20 27 20 29 % change year % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions 0 0,05 0,1 0,15 0,2 0,25 20 11 20 13 20 15 20 17 20 19 20 21 20 23 20 25 20 27 20 29 % change year % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 262 all carbon tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. It is evi- dent from Figure 2 that the positive effect on GDP in all four scenarios is stronger than in case of the projection in which all generated tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. This matches our expectations as additional relief of labour costs through a decrease in social security contributions payable by the employers or the workers translates into an increase in household purchasing power and in turn an increase in GDP . The positive effect is stronger in case of revenue recycling through a decrease in worker’s social security contributions in the entire period at hand (both relative to the first scenario). The difference between the two revenue recycling options is decreasing through the examined period. The reasons for this can be found in higher household consumption expenditure (see previous section) which is the largest component of GDP . The result is similar in the case where green tax revenue is allocated for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in social security contri- butions in 2017 and beyond. Decrease of social security contributions for the workers has a stronger positive effect on household consumption expenditure than a decrease of social security contributions for the employers (both in comparison to the first scenario). In this case, too, the differences between the two scenarios are gradually decreasing through the years. Figure 2 also shows that the best scenarios from the aspect of revenue recycling are the ones that decrease social security contributions for the workers (scenarios 2 and 4). These two scenarios are only different in the first five years; after that, their results tend to match. Similar match can be seen between the two scenarios in which the employer’s social security contributions are reduced. It should again be noted that the differences be- tween all scenarios in terms of discrepancy relative to the first scenario are relatively small. Figure 2: Comparison between different forms of carbon tax revenue recycling from the aspect of effect on gross domestic product, RGDP . Source: E3ME program and own calculations. 1 0 0,1 0,2 0,3 0,4 0,5 0,6 20 11 20 13 20 15 20 17 20 19 20 21 20 23 20 25 20 27 20 29 % change year % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions 0 0,05 0,1 0,15 0,2 0,25 20 11 20 13 20 15 20 17 20 19 20 21 20 23 20 25 20 27 20 29 % change year % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 263 Effect on total manufacturing output Following is a presentation of the effect of carbon tax introduction on manufacturing output (QR) in case of different forms of recycling. Figure 3 compares four scenarios to the projection in which all carbon tax revenue, is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). It is evident from Figure 3 that the positive effect on manufacturing output in all four scenarios (2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th) is stronger than in case of the projection in which all generated tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. Higher cost relief through a decrease in social security contributions of the employer or the worker and the re- sulting improvement in cost efficiency appears to motivate total manufacturing output as well. Recycling through a reduction in social security contributions of the workers has a more posi- tive effect on production than recycling through decrease in social security contributions for the employers in the period 2012–2030 (both relative to the first scenario). The result is similar in the case where we allocate the green tax revenue for covering the budget deficit in the pe- riod from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in social security contributions in 2017 and there- after. In both cases, decrease of social security contributions for the workers has a stronger positive effect on manufacturing output than a decrease in the employer’s social security con- tributions. Again, the differences between all scenarios in terms of discrepancy relative to the first scenario are relatively small. Figure 3: Comparison between different forms of carbon tax revenue recycling from the aspect of total manufacturing output, QR. Source: E3ME program and own calculations. 2 0 0,05 0,1 0,15 0,2 0,25 20 11 20 13 20 15 20 17 20 19 20 21 20 23 20 25 20 27 20 29 % change year % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions 0 0,1 0,2 0,3 0,4 0,5 0,6 0,7 20 11 20 13 20 15 20 17 20 19 20 21 20 23 20 25 20 27 20 29 % change year % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 264 Effect on employment Following is a presentation of the effect of carbon tax introduction on employment (YRE) in case of different forms of recycling. Four scenarios are compared to the projection in which all carbon tax revenue, is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). Figure 4 shows that the positive effect on employment in all four scenarios (2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th) is stronger than in case of the projection in which all generated tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. Higher cost relief through a decrease in social security contributions (of the employer or the worker) evidently has a positive effect on employment, which is also consistent with the previous two figures. Revenue recycling through a decrease of the employer’s social security contributions has a stronger effect on employment than revenue recycling through worker’s social security contributions, but only in the short run until the year 2014. In the long run, the opposite is true; after 2015, the difference between the second and the third scenario is constant. If carbon tax revenue is allocated for covering the budget deficit in the period 2012–2016 and for a decrease in social security contributions in 2017 and beyond, the conclusion is similar. In this case, too, revenue recycling has a stronger effect in the short run (until 2018) if the employer’s social security contributions are decreased. Differences between all analyzed scenarios are relatively small in terms of discrepancy relative to the first scenario. Figure 4: Comparison between different forms of recycling in case of carbon tax introduc- tion from the aspect of employment, YRE Source: E3ME program and own calculations. 2 0 0,05 0,1 0,15 0,2 0,25 20 11 20 13 20 15 20 17 20 19 20 21 20 23 20 25 20 27 20 29 % change year % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions 0 0,1 0,2 0,3 0,4 0,5 0,6 0,7 20 11 20 13 20 15 20 17 20 19 20 21 20 23 20 25 20 27 20 29 % change year % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 265 5. CONCLUSION The main goal of the environmental tax reform is economic and environmental improve- ment. Environmental dividend involves reduction in emissions, while economic dividend has to do with improved cost competitiveness, higher growth, and higher employment. Our primary goal was to determine the effect of an extra carbon tax (EUR 15 per ton of CO2 i.e. EUR 55 per ton of carbon) in the period 2012–2030 on Slovenian economy, in order to determine whether a carbon tax would indeed yield a double dividend. In the first section, we analysed the effects of the introduction of a yearly carbon tax (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) relative to the baseline projection (in which no tax is introduced) in the period 2012–2030, using the E3ME model. Our analysis has shown that average prices of fuels will increase which will reduce demand for fuels. Higher prices will also lead to lower household consumption expenditure, which would decrease aggregate demand and result in a drop of GDP. GDP would be additionally decreased in the short run by lower export competitiveness of the Slovenian economy, resulting from higher prices, as we assumed that the change in prices would not affect the European economy. In the medium and long run, the effect of carbon tax on the change in GDP , relative to the baseline scenario (i.e. no car- bon tax), is always lower. This conforms to our expectations and the theoretical findings as economic agents require some time to adjust to the new circumstances. The E3ME model has shown that Slovenian export sector would look to introduce new technological solutions and updates, thereby neutralizing relatively quickly the negative effects of the introduction of the carbon tax on the competitiveness of the Slovenian economy. Similar dynamics and oscillation as in GDP can be observed in manufacturing output and employment. Green- house emissions, too, are reduced in the model, at approximately the same rate. Economic policy developers in Slovenia, as in many other European countries with imple- mented environmental tax reform, should be aware that introduction of a carbon tax in Slovenia would have more negative effects in the short run than in the medium and long run. It is therefore of key importance for the success of the green tax reform to introduce the extra carbon tax gradually, transparently, and predictably. This would allow enough time for economic agents to adapt, and for economic policy developers to evaluate the first effects of the green tax reform and to make any adjustments if discrepancies from the planned goals are identified in the course of the reform. This would also prevent recurring discussions as to the urgency of increase of some tax rates and political pressure to de- crease such rates as a result of higher prices of oil and petrochemicals in the global market. In the second section, we used the E3ME model to analyze the effects of different forms of tax revenue recycling, either through a decrease in the budget deficit or through a decrease of social security contributions payable by either the employers or the workers, in case of a yearly carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15 per ton of CO2 in the period 2012–2030. Our analysis has shown that recycling through lowering the social security contributions for workers (2nd and 4th scenario) and employers (3rd and 5th scenario) have a stronger posi- tive effect on household consumption expenditure than the scenario in which all revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). Differences between the ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 266 recycling scenarios are relatively small. Additional relief through a decrease in social security contributions in case of an extra carbon tax would increase the purchasing power of the gen- eral population (household consumption expenditure), which would in turn increase the GDP . Higher cost relief through a decrease in social security contributions also has a positive effect on total manufacturing output and employment. We have also shown that recycling through a decrease in social security contributions of workers has a stronger positive eco- nomic effect than recycling through a decrease in employers’ social security contributions in the entire period at hand. The result is similar in the case where we allocate the green tax revenue for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in workers’ or employers’ social security contributions in 2017 and thereafter. Policy implications for the Slovenian government are twofold. Firstly, scenarios in which all revenue is allocated exclusively for lowering the social security contributions for workers/em- ployers have a stronger positive economic effect than the scenario in which all revenue is al- located exclusively for covering the budget deficit. Secondly, the optimal fiscal instrument for improving the environmental (first dividend) and economic welfare (second dividend) seems to be recycling through a decrease in social security contributions of workers. The reasons can be found in the fact that a decrease in employers’ social security contributions would translate to a lower extent into an increase in net wages and the resulting increase in consumption than it would be the case if social security contributions were decreased for the workers. However, an environmental tax reform cannot be successful if the political reality in Slo- venia is disregarded. As a rule, economists design optimum policy mixes for the attain- ment of certain goals; however, politics often requires compromises. Experience from other countries has shown that the key to their success was the high rate of consent of all political parties and civil society regarding the urgency of an environmental tax reform. Therefore, the Slovenian government should inform the public about the negative effects of an extra carbon tax. Public support will be higher, if an effective system of measures is put into place to neutralize the harmful effects of the additional carbon tax. REFERENCES Albrecht, J. (2006). The use of consumption taxes to re-launch green tax reforms. International Review of Law and Economics, 26(1), 88–103. Barker, T.S. & Ekins, P . & Johnstone, N. (1995). Global Warming and Energy Demand. London: Routledge. Baron, R. (1997). Economic/Fiscal Instruments: Competitiveness Issues Related to Carbon/Energy Taxation Policies and Measures for Common Action. Working Paper No. 14. Paris: OECD. Benoit, B. (2000). Environmental tax reform: does it work? A survey of the empirical evidence. Ecological Eco- nomics, 34(1), 19–32. Berkhout, G., Ferrer-i-Carbonell A. & Muskens, A.C. (2001). Het effect van de REB op huishoudelijk energie- gevruik. EEN econometrische analyse. Amsterdam. Bentzen, J. & Engsted, T. (1993). Short- and long-run elasticities in energy demand: a cointegration approach. Energy Economics, 15(1) 9-16. Bovenberg, L. & Goulder, L.H. (1997). Cost of environmentally motivated taxes in the presence of other taxes: general equilibrium analyses. National Tax Journal, 50(1), 59–87. A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 267 Camecon (2012). Teaching course. 15th-16th March, 2012. Carraro, C., Galeotti, M. & Gallo, M. (1996). Environmental taxation and unemployment: Some evidence on the ‘double dividend hypothesis’ in Europe. Journal of Public Economics, 62(1/2), 141-181. Ciaschini, M., Pretalori, R., Severini, F., Socci, C. (2012): Regional Double Dividend from Environmental Tax Reform: An Application from the Italian Economy. Research in Economics, 66(3): 273-283. Clinch, P., Dunne, L. & Dresner, S. (2006). Environmental and wider implications of political impediments to environmental tax reform. Energy Policy, 34(8), 960–970. Coxhead, I. (2000). Tax Reform and the Environment in Developing Economies: Is a Double Dividend Possible? Wisconsin-Madison Agricultural and Applied Economics Staff Paper No. 431. Madison: University of Wiscon- sin-Madison. Doornik, J. (2007). Ox: An Object-Oriented Matrix Language. London: Timberlake Consultants Press. De Mooij, R.A. (1999). The double dividend of an environmental tax reform. In Bergh, V. (Ed.), Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics (pp. 600-613). London: Edward Elgar. E3ME Manual (2012). http://www.camecon.com/Libraries/Downloadable_Files/E3ME_Manual.sflb.ashx (Accessed on 20.12.2012) E3ME (2014). Technical Manual, Version 6.0. Cambridge: Cambridge Econometrics. Ekins, P. (2009). Resource Productivity, Environmental Tax Reform and Sustainable Growth in Europe. Berlin: Anglo-German Foundation. Engle, R.F. & C.W .J. Granger, C.W .J. (1987). Cointegration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica, 55, 251-76. European Commission (2010). EU energy trends to 2030 – update 2009. Brussels: European Commission. European Commission (2012). Taxation trend in the EU. Brussels: European Commission. Franzén, M. & Sterner, T (1995). Long-run Demand Elasticities for Gasoline. In Barker, T. & Johnstone, N. & Ekins, P . (eds.), Global Warming and Energy Elasticities. London: Routledge. Fraser, I. & W aschik, R. (2013): The Double Dividend Hypothesis in CGE Model: Specific factors and the Carbon Case. Energy Economics, 39, 283-295. Gimenez, E. & Rodriguez, M. (2010). Reevaluating the first and the second dividends of environmental tax reforms. Energy Policy, 38(11), 6654–6661. Glomm, G., Kawaguchi, D. & Sepulveda, F. (2008). Green taxes and double dividends in a dynamic economy. Journal of policy modeling, 30(1), 19-32. Goulder, L.H. (1995). Environmental taxation and the ‘‘double dividend’’: a reader’s guide. International Tax and Public Finance, 2(2), 155–182. Hansen, M. & Holger, H. (2000). Green tax reform in Denmark. In Schlegelmilch, Kai (Ed.), Green Budget reform in Europe: Countries at the forefront (pp. 139-145). Berlin: Springer. Hendry, D. F. & Pagan, A. & Sargan, J.D. (1984). Dynamic specification. In Griliches, Z. & Intriligator, M.D. (eds), Handbook of Econometrics, Vol II (pp. 1023-1100). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Hoerner, B. (2001). Environmental tax reform: The European Experience. Washingtom DC: Center for Sustain- able Economy. Holmlund, B. & Kolm, A.S. (2000). Environmental tax reform in a small open economy with structural unem- ployment. International Tax and Public Finance, 7(3), 315–333. Hunt, L. & Manning, N. (1989). Energy price- and income-elasticities of demand: some estimates for the UK using the cointegration procedure. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 36(2), 183-193. Johansson, O. & Schipper, L. (1997). Measuring the long-run fuel demand of cars. Journal of Transport Econom- ics and Policy, 31(3), 277-292. Johansson, B. (2000). The carbon tax in Sweden. In: OECD, Innovation and the Environment (pp. 85-94). Paris: OECD. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 268 Koskela, E. & Schob, R. (1999). Alleviating unemployment: the case for green tax reform. European Economic Review, 43(9), 1723–1746. Kosonen, K. & Nicodème, G. (2009). The role of fiscal instruments in environmental policy. Working paper No. 2719, Munchen: CESifo. Labandeira, X. & Labeaga, J. (1999). Combining inpt-ouput analysis and microsimulations to acces the effects of carbon taxation on spanish households. Fiscal studies, 20(3), 305-320. Labandeira, X., Labeaga, J.M. & Rodríguez, M. (2004). Green tax reforms in Spain. European Environment, 14(5), 290–299. Hua Li, Longyang Ren (2012). China’s Provincial Tax Structure Optimization: Double Dividend of Energy and Efficiency. Finance & Trade Economics, 10(3). Ludewig, D., Meyer, B. & Schlegelmilch, K. (2010). Greening the Budget: Pricing Carbon and Cutting Energy Sub- sidies to reduce the financial deficit in Germany. Washington DC: Heinrich Boll Stiftung. Manresa, A. & Sancho, F. (2005). Implementing a double dividend: recycling ecotaxes towards lower labour taxes. Energy Policy, 33(12), 1577–1585 Morgenstern, R. (1995). Environmental Taxes: Dead or Alive? Discussion Paper 95-03. Washington, DC: Re- sources for the Future. OECD (2007). Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. Parry, I. & Oates, W . (1998). Policy Analysis in a Second Best World. Discussion paper No. 98-48. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Patuelli, R., Nijkamp, P . & Pels, E. (2005). Environmental tax reform and the double dividend: A meta-analytical performance assessment. Ecological Economics, 55(4), 564-583. Pigou, A.C. (1920). The Economics of Welfare. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson. Roed, L. (2006). Distributional effects of environmental taxes on transportation – evidence from Engel curves in the USA. Journal of Consumer Policy, 29(39), 301-318. Sandmo, A. (1975). Optimal taxation in the presence of externalities. Swedish Journal of Economics, 77(1), 86–98. Schöb, R. (2003). The Double Dividend Hypothesis of Environmental Taxes: A Survey. Working paper No. 946. Munchen: CESifo. Speck, S., Jilkova, J. (2009). Design of environmental tax reforms in Europe. Carbon energy taxation: lessons from Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ščasný, M., Píša, V ., Pollitt, H. & Chewpreecha, U. (2009). Analyzing Macroeconomic Effects of Environmental Taxation in the Czech Republic with the Econometric E3ME Model. Journal of Economics and Finance, 59(5), 460-491. Tiezzi, S. (2001). The welfare effects of carbon taxation in Italian households. Working paper No. 337. Siena: Di- partimento di Economica Politica, Universita degli Studi di Siena. Tuladhar, S.D. & Wilcoxen, P .J. (1999). An Econometric Look at the Double Dividend Hypothesis. National Tax Association Proceedings, 57-62. Turner, K., Pearce, D. & Bateman, I. (1994). Environmental economics: An elementary introduction. Prentice Hall: Pearson Education. West, S. & Williams, R. (2004). Estimates from a Consumer demands system: Implication for the incidence of environmental taxes. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 47(3), 535-558. Yohe, G.W ., Lasco, R.D., Ahmad, Q.K., Arnell, N.W ., Cohen, S.J., Hope, C., Janetos, A.C. & Perez, R.T. (2007). Perspectives on climate change and sustainability. In Parry, M.L., Canziani, O.F., Palutikof, J.P ., van der Linden, P .J. & Hanson, C.E. (Eds.), Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Work- ing Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (pp. 811-841). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 269 APPENDIX Table A1: PRIMES (Baseline 2009) for Slovenia. 3 Table A1: PRIMES (Baseline 2009) for Slovenia. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 270 Source: EU energy trends to 2030 – update 2009 (2010), pp. 114-115. 4 A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 271 Table A2: Equation summary. Source: E3ME Manual (2012). Table A3: Baseline assumptions, complete with sources. DATA SOURCES World assumptions 1. Commodity prices - food CE own assumptions - beverages CE own assumptions - agricultural raw materials CE own assumptions - metals CE own assumptions - energy IEA, PRIMES - oil IEA, PRIMES - global inflation CE own assumptions Region specific assumptions 1. Exchange rates DG ECFIN AMECO database over historical, fixed afterwards 5 Table A2: Equation summary. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 272 - euro exchange rates (WREX) - purchasing power standard (WRPX) 2. Interest rates DG ECFIN AMECO database over historical, fixed afterwards - short-term rate (WRSR) - long-term rate (WRLR) 3. Macro variables Not use for E3ME regions (endogenous) forecasts calibrated to PRIMES 2009 projection Historical data stored in databank from Eurostat Other Regions (CE own assumptions + results from E3MG modelling) - GDP (WGDP) - GDP deflator (WHUC) 4. Government consumption (WRSG, GW01, GW02,GW03) Eurostat, Cambridge Econometrics - defence - fixed after last year of historical data - education - fixed after last year of historical data - health - fixed after last year of historical data 5. Fiscal policy DG ECFIN AMECO database, DG TAX AND CUSTOMS “T axes in Europe” database over historical period, fixed afterwards - taxes on goods and services (WITR) - standard rate on V AT (WSVT) - taxes on income and capital gains (WDTR) - taxes on international trade (WTTR) - subsidies and other transfers to households (WBNR) - social security taxes paid by employees (WSSR) - social security taxes paid by employers (WERS) 6. Population (WRPO, P AR1…. P AR6) Eurostat population projections - total population - male/female split - children/working-age/ old-age pensioner split A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 273 7. Labor force (LRP1, LRP2) Not use for E3ME regions (endogenous) Historical data stored in databank from Eurostat LFS - male/female participation rates Source: E3ME program. Table A4: Baseline assumptions for Slovenia and the world in the E3ME model. Source: E3ME program. 7 Table A4: Baseline assumptions for Slovenia and the world in the E3ME model. SLOVENIA Code Description unit 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 WREX01 Ex hange rate local currency per euro 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 WRPX01 Ex hange rate: PPP (not used) local currency per euro 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 1.386 WRSR01 Interest rate: short run (not used) percent 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 0.046 WRLR01 Interest rate: long run percent 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 0.038 WGDP01_MA06 G DP (not used for E3ME regions) year on year growth 1.379 1.937 2.451 3.248 3.248 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 3.541 WHUC01_MA12 inflation (not used for E3ME regions) annual rate 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 WRSG01_MA02 G overnm ent spending year on year growth 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 1.029 GW 01_DEFENCE G overnm ent spending: Defence share of total governm ent spending 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 GW02_EDUCATION G overnm ent spending: Education share of total governm ent spending 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 0.245 GW 03_HEA LTH G overnm ent spending: Health share of total governm ent spending 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 0.297 WITR01_TAX_G&S Tax : Indirect 1+share of household spending 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 1.184 WSVT01_TAX_VAT T a x: VA T Rate 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 WDTR01_TAX_INC Tax : Direct Rate (wages) 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 0.174 WTTR01_TAX_TRADE Tax: Import tariffs (not used) Rate 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 1.002 WBNR01_SUBS&TRANS Benefit Payment share of wage 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 0.366 WSSR01_SS_TOTAL Soc. sec em ployees' contibution rate 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 0.186 WERS01_SS_ERS Soc. sec em ployers' contibution rate 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 0.136 WRPO_POP_TOTAL Population year on year growth 0.276 0.237 0.209 0.198 0.168 0.14 0.116 0.087 0.056 0.03 -0.008 -0.035 -0.07 -0.104 -0.138 -0.161 -0.185 -0.208 -0.225 -0.245 -0.264 PAR1_M_CHILD Population: m ale 0-15 share of total population 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.069 0.068 0.067 0.067 0.066 0.065 0.064 0.063 PAR2_F_CHILD Population: fem ale 0-15 share of total population 0.066 0.066 0.067 0.067 0.067 0.068 0.068 0.068 0.068 0.069 0.069 0.068 0.068 0.067 0.067 0.066 0.065 0.064 0.063 0.063 0.062 PAR3_M_WORK_AG E Population: m ale 16-64 share of total population 0.357 0.357 0.356 0.354 0.352 0.35 0.347 0.345 0.342 0.339 0.336 0.333 0.331 0.329 0.327 0.325 0.324 0.322 0.32 0.319 0.317 PAR4_F_WORK_AG E Population: fem ale 16-64 share of total population 0.339 0.339 0.338 0.336 0.334 0.332 0.329 0.327 0.324 0.321 0.319 0.317 0.314 0.313 0.311 0.31 0.308 0.307 0.305 0.304 0.303 PAR5_M_OLD Population: m ale 65+ share of total population 0.066 0.066 0.067 0.069 0.071 0.074 0.076 0.079 0.082 0.085 0.088 0.091 0.094 0.097 0.099 0.102 0.104 0.107 0.109 0.112 0.114 PAR6_F_OLD Population: fem ale 65+ share of total population 0.102 0.102 0.102 0.104 0.105 0.107 0.109 0.111 0.113 0.116 0.118 0.12 0.123 0.125 0.127 0.13 0.132 0.134 0.137 0.139 0.141 LRP1_M_PARTN_RATE Participation rate: male (not used) percent of m ale working population 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 0.761 LRP2_F_PARTN_RATE Participation rate: female (not used) percent of fem ale working poulation 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 0.675 W ORLD Code Description unit 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 PFMG(01) Com m odity Price: Food year on year growth 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 PFMG(02) Commodity Price: Beverages year on year growth 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 PFMG(03) Commodity Price: Agriculture Raw Material year on year growth 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 PFMG(04) Commodity Price: Metals & Minerals year on year growth 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.2 PFMG(05) Com m odity Price: Energy year on year growth 6.031 6.929 6.929 6.929 6.929 6.929 5.861 5.861 5.861 5.861 5.861 4.566 4.566 4.566 4.566 4.566 4.566 4.566 4.566 4.02 4.02 PFMG(06) Com m odity Price: Brent oil year on year growth 20.586 2.27 2.27 2.27 2.27 2.27 6.367 6.367 6.367 6.367 6.367 5.126 5.126 5.126 5.126 5.126 5.126 5.126 5.126 4.814 4.814 PFMG(07) Agregate G lobal Inflation year on year growth 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 274 Table A5: Values of economic, environmental, and energy variables in different scenarios for the period 2011-2030. Source: E3ME program and own calculations. Appendix 1: Aggregate demand for energy and its parameters for Slovenia. In Table A6 we show the specification of aggregated demand for energy that is used in the E3ME model. The equation is based on the work of Barker, Ekins and Johnston (1995), Hunt and Manning (1989) and Bentzen and Engsted (1993). »The aggregate energy equation considers the total fuel used (summation of 12 fuel types) in thousand tonnes of oil equivalent (th.toe) by 19 fuel users. The demand for energy by a fuel user is dependent on the ‚activity‘ for the fuel user. This is chosen as gross economic 8 SCENARIO RECYCLING / YEAR 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 Green revenues from a cabon tax baseline scenario / 00000000000000000000 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) all 0 144.639 147.335 150.279 153.514 154.514 155.882 157.703 159.536 160.94 159.514 158.126 157.011 156.118 155.148 153.213 151.235 149.65 148.493 147.099 baseline scenario / 28749.77 29436.21 30415.7 31443.8 32502.98 33411.88 34355.28 35349.36 36385.24 37449.73 38176.75 38926.43 39697.25 40507.05 41345.79 41865.08 42408.16 42959.87 43502.27 44051.21 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 28749.77 29415.28 30322.49 31386.87 32439.38 33356.36 34305.07 35300.83 36336.85 37402.58 38133.77 38889.22 39663.53 40473.73 41309.04 41825.57 42374.68 42926.33 43462.15 44009.93 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 28749.77 29478.9 30380.23 31450.78 32501.63 33419.58 34367.1 35350.45 36384.39 37445.14 38171.98 38916.1 39691.16 40504.11 41344.97 41858.34 42407.76 42959.18 43488.57 44029.78 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 28749.77 29446.68 30353.49 31427.92 32481 33394.67 34337.66 35326.3 36362.72 37426.74 38155.76 38906.42 39681.3 40491.9 41329.51 41846.16 42394.95 42944.81 43476.59 44021.18 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social security contributions 28749.77 29415.28 30322.49 31386.87 32439.38 33356.36 34360.18 35339.48 36378.32 37451.36 38185.97 38932.13 39706.17 40515.79 41349.45 41852.42 42399.23 42950.67 43487.95 44039.86 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 28749.77 29415.28 30322.49 31386.87 32439.38 33356.36 34328.9 35318.64 36363.46 37433.86 38163.37 38911.42 39684.97 40495.51 41331.45 41843.31 42391.35 42941.27 43476.87 44026.62 baseline scenario / 16705.19 16945.31 17470.62 18004.52 18550.77 19074.5 19612.02 20159.48 20729.08 21316.29 21789.22 22266.06 22770.05 23289.98 23818.74 24183.24 24543.27 24956.55 25382.57 25810 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19545.53 20096.52 20667.77 21256.98 21732.45 22210.29 22713.19 23230.92 23758.01 24122.45 24495.48 24913.65 25332.61 25754.82 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 16705.19 16975.57 17477.51 18022.34 18559.2 19085.13 19623.32 20160.12 20731.11 21320.4 21797.08 22264.55 22769.02 23288.56 23818.11 24170.78 24539.25 24958.42 25376.35 25796.2 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 16705.19 16944.68 17447.24 17989.73 18527.51 19052.41 19590.35 20132.39 20703.96 21293.73 21770.3 22242.09 22746.6 23265.72 23794.24 24151.53 24521.36 24939.85 25358.64 25779.81 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social security contributions 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19623.81 20164.48 20737.44 21328.23 21803.74 22267.61 22768.59 23287 23817.9 24169.99 24541.67 24960.25 25379.2 25801.98 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19595.12 20140.13 20712.34 21300.78 21774.67 22242.68 22744.26 23262.72 23792.73 24149.85 24522.38 24941.19 25360.65 25783.29 baseline scenario / 16705.19 16945.31 17470.62 18004.52 18550.77 19074.5 19612.02 20159.48 20729.08 21316.29 21789.22 22266.06 22770.05 23289.98 23818.74 24183.24 24543.27 24956.55 25382.57 25810 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19545.53 20096.52 20667.77 21256.98 21732.45 22210.29 22713.19 23230.92 23758.01 24122.45 24495.48 24913.65 25332.61 25754.82 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 16705.19 16975.57 17477.51 18022.34 18559.2 19085.13 19623.32 20160.12 20731.11 21320.4 21797.08 22264.55 22769.02 23288.56 23818.11 24170.78 24539.25 24958.42 25376.35 25796.2 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 16705.19 16944.68 17447.24 17989.73 18527.51 19052.41 19590.35 20132.39 20703.96 21293.73 21770.3 22242.09 22746.6 23265.72 23794.24 24151.53 24521.36 24939.85 25358.64 25779.81 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social security contributions 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19623.81 20164.48 20737.44 21328.23 21803.74 22267.61 22768.59 23287 23817.9 24169.99 24541.67 24960.25 25379.2 25801.98 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19595.12 20140.13 20712.34 21300.78 21774.67 22242.68 22744.26 23262.72 23792.73 24149.85 24522.38 24941.19 25360.65 25783.29 baseline scenario / 21531.41 22199.45 22996.59 23848.7 24729.97 25510.09 26305 27079.24 27880.9 28705.55 29188.84 29579.96 30044.5 30518 31034.2 31365.94 31634.17 31984.08 32300.69 32646.13 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 21531.41 22214.99 22980.56 23826.07 24692.9 25477.39 26276.24 27057.75 27861.56 28683.53 29166.47 29562.1 30035.12 30511.67 31026.06 31348.3 31652.37 32012.02 32319.98 32665.44 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 21531.41 22229.12 22990.89 23850.03 24719.05 25502.39 26295.74 27072.12 27872.67 28688.84 29167.51 29558.76 30035.01 30513.88 31034.17 31358.98 31651.61 32016 32318.01 32659.15 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 21531.41 22211.22 22976.19 23839.81 24714.27 25495.9 26284.69 27062.03 27864.91 28685.59 29167.42 29564.31 30038.1 30513.06 31029.63 31359.26 31654.73 32013.31 32315.45 32658.35 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social security contributions 21531.41 22214.99 22980.56 23826.07 24692.9 25477.39 26288.89 27055.07 27870.52 28696.19 29179.96 29571.86 30047.22 30522.01 31034.96 31350.33 31652.39 32008.75 32315.32 32662.03 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 21531.41 22214.99 22980.56 23826.07 24692.9 25477.39 26266.32 27043.07 27865.38 28694.51 29175 29566.49 30037.94 30513.28 31029.36 31355.16 31657.81 32011.4 32315.07 32660.95 baseline scenario / 936.692 950.426 955.094 955.764 958.411 952.612 946.927 938.577 932.254 925.688 920.588 913.883 909.383 905.041 901.945 894.97 887.232 880.346 873.976 869.069 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 936.692 950.497 953.889 953.042 955.141 949.1 943.516 935.464 929.486 923.195 918.308 911.838 907.599 903.398 900.288 893.212 886.057 879.566 873.35 868.53 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 936.692 952.573 957.562 958.191 960.549 954.568 948.615 939.884 933.233 926.34 921.176 914.372 910.114 905.951 903.019 895.697 888.096 881.357 874.887 869.867 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 936.692 953.847 957.965 957.848 959.617 953.441 947.391 938.413 931.928 925.27 920.258 913.345 909.153 905.006 902.028 894.562 887.215 880.625 874.298 869.396 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social security contributions 936.692 950.497 953.889 953.042 955.141 949.1 945.369 938.196 933.23 927.152 922.413 915.526 910.96 906.343 902.984 895.451 888.059 881.422 875.185 870.382 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 936.692 950.497 953.889 953.042 955.141 949.1 946.645 938.51 932.958 926.643 921.709 914.505 909.912 905.366 902.092 894.496 887.281 880.734 874.513 869.717 baseline scenario / 5588.252 5737.804 5874.773 5998.528 6122.417 6186.53 6258.1 6330.867 6398.466 6463.33 6332.618 6210.716 6091.337 5971.548 5854.552 5768.035 5689.808 5612.959 5535.926 5457.153 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 5588.252 5699.225 5801.967 5910.516 6027.753 6082.999 6146.05 6218.732 6292.517 6359.086 6221.624 6089.353 5966.265 5851.007 5738.6 5651.438 5565.019 5486.641 5416.851 5343.681 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 5588.252 5699.981 5805.95 5914.157 6031.337 6086.616 6150.177 6222.895 6296.066 6362.511 6224.386 6091.057 5966.674 5851.668 5740.395 5654.128 5568.177 5487.795 5416.669 5343.986 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 5588.252 5703.375 5806.024 5908.469 6024.208 6085.302 6154.044 6224.437 6292.099 6356.679 6222.169 6092.201 5968.397 5851.377 5738.25 5651.396 5567.058 5489.025 5417.842 5343.073 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social security contributions 5588.252 5699.225 5801.967 5910.516 6027.753 6082.999 6146.645 6223.044 6296.215 6362.05 6224.478 6092.933 5969.082 5853.194 5740.442 5653.166 5566.013 5487.111 5417.339 5344.526 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 5588.252 5699.225 5801.967 5910.516 6027.753 6082.999 6150.509 6222.179 6289.215 6355.302 6224.07 6095.759 5969.932 5849.961 5736.272 5651.136 5567.327 5489.403 5417.561 5342.396 baseline scenario / 6528.858 6735.286 6929.519 7113.159 7305.409 7421.845 7549.201 7677.035 7798.161 7916.722 7704.82 7521.981 7359.104 7208.643 7072.313 7047.299 7031.582 7019.494 7007.009 6991.417 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 6528.858 6679.237 6836.475 7007.4 7193.944 7299.16 7414.321 7541.112 7670.133 7791.199 7571.272 7375.161 7207.594 7063.331 6933.324 6906.806 6879.445 6864.735 6861.451 6852.784 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 6528.858 6680.491 6841.556 7011.197 7197.421 7303.375 7420.242 7547.516 7675.336 7795.493 7574.27 7376.883 7208.198 7064.885 6936.641 6911.035 6884.056 6866.505 6861.389 6853.399 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 6528.858 6685.019 6841.814 7004.185 7188.617 7301.797 7425.046 7549.017 7669.717 7787.832 7571.796 7378.862 7210.618 7064.275 6933.412 6907.077 6882.391 6868.113 6862.943 6852.137 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social security contributions 6528.858 6679.237 6836.475 7007.4 7193.944 7299.16 7415.302 7546.529 7674.064 7794.156 7574.749 7380.27 7211.954 7066.593 6935.68 6908.626 6880.418 6865.489 6862.725 6854.685 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 6528.858 6679.237 6836.475 7007.4 7193.944 7299.16 7420.551 7545.693 7665.209 7785.534 7574.371 7383.883 7212.714 7061.986 6930.139 6906.192 6882.481 6868.658 6862.821 6851.513 baseline scenario / 3144.918 3140.383 3144.66 3156.688 3174.105 3182.884 3195.34 3212.91 3235.262 3260.783 3303.043 3347.844 3396.56 3449.189 3506.829 3552.643 3598.905 3642.847 3684.911 3730.16 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 3144.918 3255.683 3262.142 3270.724 3287.534 3298.071 3312.47 3330.179 3351.101 3375.623 3418.701 3464.836 3514.412 3566.701 3623.994 3670.967 3719.383 3764.525 3807.132 3853.669 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 3144.918 3255.151 3261.36 3271.114 3288.359 3298.943 3312.897 3330.404 3351.084 3375.115 3417.795 3463.749 3513.401 3565.553 3622.774 3669.708 3718.03 3763.33 3805.992 3852.584 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 3144.918 3254.813 3261.43 3271.553 3288.754 3298.492 3311.932 3329.914 3351.437 3375.757 3418.011 3463.634 3513.341 3565.882 3623.334 3670.273 3718.387 3763.46 3806.219 3853.038 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social security contributions 3144.918 3255.683 3262.142 3270.724 3287.534 3298.071 3312.327 3329.656 3351.871 3376.649 3419.513 3465.23 3514.767 3566.705 3623.515 3670.092 3718.494 3763.498 3806.108 3852.698 carbon tax of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 3144.918 3255.683 3262.142 3270.724 3287.534 3298.071 3311.844 3329.706 3352.208 3376.789 3418.878 3464.365 3514.366 3567.033 3624.048 3670.382 3718.387 3763.411 3806.358 3853.222 Total demand for energy in thousand toe (FRO) Average fuel (energy) price including taxes in EURO/toe (PJRT) Gross domestic product in million of euro (RGDP) Household consumption expenidtores in million of euro (RSC) Export in million of euro (RSX) Total manufacturing output in million EUR (QR) Emplyment in thousands (YRE) Greenhouse gas emissions in CO2 equivalent thousands of tons of carbon A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 275 output for most sectors, but household fuel demand is a function of total consumers‘ expenditure. A restriction is imposed such that as activity increases then demand for energy use will not decline (all other factors being equal). The average price ratio captures the effect of prices relative to the fuel used, and is de- flated by unit costs. The equations have been tested so that relative price increases cause demand to fall but relative price decreases have no effect. Such asymmetrical price ef- fects in aggregate energy demand equations have been the subject of other research (Gately, 1993; Walker and Wirl, 1993; Grubb, 1995). The idea is that because energy is used via capital stock with a long lifetime, and since technical change is progressive and is not generally reversed, when energy prices rise and energy savings are introduced, then when energy prices fall again, these savings are not reversed i.e. energy demand responds to rises in real prices, but not falls. The effect changes the properties of the model in a non-linear fashion: if in the base run real energy prices fall over the projec- tion period, then increases in energy taxes will have no effect until they start to increase real prices (one year to the next, not compared to the base). The long-run price elasticity for road fuel is imposed at -0.7 for all regions, also Slovenia, following the research on long-run demand (Franzen and Sterner, 1995) and (Johansson and Schipper, 1997). The measures of research and development expenditure and investment capture the ef- fect of new ways of decreasing energy demand (energy saving technical progress) and the elimination of inefficient technologies, such as energy saving techniques replacing the old inefficient use of energy. Research and development expenditure in industries 16-18 (machinery) and 19 (motor vehicles) for the EU as a whole take into account spillover effects from international companies.« (E3ME Manual, 2012, page 49-50). Tabel A6: Specification of agregate demand for energy. Co-integrating dynamic equation: DLN(FR0(.)) [total fuel used by fuel users] = BFR0(,.1) [constant] + BFR0(.,2) * DLN(FRY(.)) [activity measure] + BFR0(.,3) * DLN(PREN(.)) [average price ratio] + BFR0(.,4) * DLN(FRTD(.)) [R&D by fuel user] + BFR0(.,5) * DLN(ZRDM) [EU R&D in machinery] + BFR0(.,6) * DLN(ZRDT) [EU R&D in transport] + BFR0(.,7) * DLN(FRK(.)) [investment by fuel user] + BFR0(.,8) * DRDEU [German unification] + BFR0(.,9) * D09R [2009 recession dummy] + BFR0(.,10) * DLN(FR0(-1)) [lagged changes in fuel use] ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW | VOL. 16 | No. 3 | 2015 276 Co-integrating long-term equation: DLN(FR0(.)) [total fuel used by fuel users] = BFR0(.,11) * ECM(-1) [lagged error correction] + BFR0(,.12) [constant] + BFR0(,.13) * LN(FRY(.)) [activity measure] + BFR0(.,14) * LN(PREN(.)) [average price ratio] + BFR0(.,15) * LN(FRTD(.)) [R&D by fuel user] + BFR0(.,16) * LN(ZRDM) [EU R&D in machinery] + BFR0(.,17) * LN(ZRDT) [EU R&D in transport] + BFR0(.,18) * LN(FRK(.)) [investment by fuel user] + BFR0(.,19) * RDEU [German unification] + BFR0(.,20) * D09R [2009 recession dummy] + ECM [error] Identity: PREN = PFR0(.)/PRYM [average price ratio] Restrictions: BFR0(.,3 .,4 .,5 .,6 .,7 .,14 .,15.,16 .,17 .,18) <=0 [‘right sign’] BFR0(.,2), BFR0(.,13) >=0 [modeling energy demand/activity ratio] 0>BRF0(.,11)>-1 [‘right sign’] Definitions: BFR0 is a matrix of parameters FR0 is a matrix of total fuel used by 22 fuel users for 33 regions, th toe. PREN is a matrix of average price used deflated by unit cost for 33 regions, euro/toe FRY is a matrix of activity for 22 fuel users and 33 regions, m euro at 2005 prices FRTD is R&D in machinery by the EU, m euro at 2005 prices ZRDM is R&D in transport by the EU, m euro at 2005 prices ZRDT is a matrix of investment by 22 fuel users for 33 regions, m euro at 2005 prices FRK is a matrix of prices of value added at market prices for each region (2005 = 1.0, local price) PRYM is a matrix of average prices in euro/tonne of all fuels used by each fuel user PFR0 is a matrix of average prices in euro/tonne of all fuels used by each fuel user RDEU is a dummy matrix for German unification (=0 for other countries) D09R is a dummy matrix for 2009 recession (=0 until 2008, =1 from 2009 onward) (.) indicates that a matrix is defined across sectors LN indicates natural logarithm DLN indicates change in natural logarithm ECM [error] Source: E3ME Manual (2012). A. KEŠELJEVIĆ, M. KOMAN | ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION... 277 In Table A7 we show the values of estimated paramaters of agregated demand for energy for Slovenia. Tabel A7: Values of parameters of agregated demand for energy function for Slovenia. Source: E3ME model. The price elasticities of energy demand for fuel users are for example shown in column 3 and 14. Column 3 shows price elasticites of demand based on co-integrating dynamic equation, while column 14 shows long term elasticites of demand based on co-integrating long-term equation.. For example, 1% increase of average price ratio (variable PREN) causes decrease in quantity demanded for energy in road transportation for 0.7%. 9 FUEL USERS 123456789 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 Power own use & trans. 0.055 0 -0.328 0 -0.456 0 -0.473 0 0 -0.2 -0.95 7.964 0.247 -0.177 0 -0.088 -0.058 -0.027 0 0 2 O.energy own use & tra -0.064 0 0 -0.031 0 -0.64 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 5.337 0.232 -0.331 -0.086 -0.019 -0.056 -0.044 0 0 3 Iron & steel 0.02 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 0 0.6 -0.95 9.106 0.117 -0.263 -0.091 -0.249 -0.037 -0.013 0 0 4 Non-ferrous metals 0.005 0 -0.85 0 0 0 -0.169 0 0 0.095 -0.216 7.931 0.297 -0.311 -0.015 0 -0.184 -0.208 0 0 5 Chemicals 0.008 1.2 -1.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.093 -0.417 7.69 0.432 -0.253 -0.135 -0.073 -0.308 -0.011 0 0 6 Non-metallics nes 0.138 0.06 -0.273 -0.032 0 0 -0.021 0 0 0.01 -0.799 6.685 0.292 -0.279 -0.05 -0.027 -0.132 0 0 0 7 Ore-extra.(non-energy) 0.153 0 -1.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 9.544 0.751 -0.331 0 -0.166 -0.653 -0.026 0 0 8 Food, drink & tob. -0.008 1.2 -1.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.936 4.555 0.609 -0.221 -0.003 -0.14 -0.061 -0.251 0 0 9 Tex., cloth. & footw. -0.078 1.2 -0.504 -0.295 -1 0 -0.111 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 7.24 0.546 -0.269 -0.015 -0.049 -0.44 -0.08 0 0 10 Paper & pulp 0.049 0 -1.024 0 0 -1 -0.06 0 0 0.159 -0.2 4.684 0.635 -0.387 -0.005 -0.029 -0.106 -0.091 0 0 11 Engineering etc 0.065 0 -0.871 0 -1 0 -0.27 0 0 0.134 -0.2 6.39 0.406 -0.214 -0.005 -0.162 -0.155 -0.04 0 0 12 Other industry 0.076 0 0 0 0 0 -1.56 0 0 0.228 -0.95 12.476 0.709 -0.492 -0.02 -0.512 -0.278 -0.358 0 0 13 Rail transport -0.042 0.844 -0.344 0 0 0 -0.024 0 0 -0.2 -0.723 5.764 0.19 -0.212 0 -0.136 -0.043 -0.016 0 0 14 Road transport -0.107 0 -0.095 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.454 -0.574 6.184 0.602 -0.7 0 0 -0.021 -0.008 0 0 15 Air transport 0.035 0 0 0 0 0 -0.013 0 0 0.249 -0.2 5.399 0.457 -0.403 0 -0.174 0 -0.065 0 0 16 Other transp. serv. 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.146 -0.359 0 -0.08 -0.38 -0.327 0 0 17 Households -0.004 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 3.875 0.718 -0.217 0 -0.026 -0.072 -0.258 0 0 18 Other final use 0.362 0 -0.91 -0.228 0 0 -3 0 0 0.6 -0.95 5.73 0.666 -0.248 -0.049 -0.085 -0.038 -0.361 0 0 19 Non-energy use 0.124 0 -0.681 0 -1 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 7.721 0 -0.221 0 -0.003 -0.133 0 0 0 COEFFICIENTS